Jump to content
 







Main menu
   


Navigation  



Main page
Contents
Current events
Random article
About Wikipedia
Contact us
Donate
 




Contribute  



Help
Learn to edit
Community portal
Recent changes
Upload file
 








Search  

































Create account

Log in
 









Create account
 Log in
 




Pages for logged out editors learn more  



Contributions
Talk
 



















Contents

   



(Top)
 


1 History  





2 Religion and individual behaviour  



2.1  Believing  





2.2  Belonging  







3 Experimental economics of religion  





4 Religion and economic growth  



4.1  Historical aspects  





4.2  Criticisms  







5 See also  





6 References  





7 External links  














Economics of religion: Difference between revisions







Español
فارسی
Français
Bahasa Indonesia
Português
Русский
 

Edit links
 









Article
Talk
 

















Read
Edit
View history
 








Tools
   


Actions  



Read
Edit
View history
 




General  



What links here
Related changes
Upload file
Special pages
Permanent link
Page information
Cite this page
Get shortened URL
Download QR code
Wikidata item
 




Print/export  



Download as PDF
Printable version
 




In other projects  



Wikimedia Commons
 
















Appearance
   

 





Help
 

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
 


Browse history interactively
 Previous edit
Content deleted Content added
Opti6 (talk | contribs)
943 edits
Religiosity
Rescuing 1 sources and tagging 0 as dead.) #IABot (v2.0.9.5
 
(79 intermediate revisions by 43 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:

The '''economics of religion''' concerns both the application of the techniques of [[economics]] to the study of religion and the relationship between [[Economic behavior|economic]] and [[religious behaviour]]s.<ref name="Iannaccone">{{Cite journal |last=Iannaccone |first=Laurence R. |author-link=Laurence R. Iannaccone |date= 1998|title=Introduction to the Economics of Religion|journal=Journal of Economic Literature |volume=36|issue=3|pages=[https://edisciplinas.usp.br/pluginfile.php/262957/mod_resource/content/2/Iannaccone%20-%20Economics%20of%20Religion.pdf pp.1465–1495.]}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1= McCleary |first1= Rachel M. |title= The Oxford Handbook of the Economics of Religion |date= 2011 |publisher= Oxford University Press |isbn= 9780199781287 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=TRjB0DjEyIkC&q=oxford+handbook+of+economics+of+religion |language= en}}</ref> Contemporary writers on the subject trace it back to [[Adam Smith]] (1776).<ref>• {{Cite journal |last=Iannaccone |first=Laurence R. |author-link=Laurence R. Iannaccone |date= 1998|title=Introduction to the Economics of Religion|journal=Journal of Economic Literature |volume=36 |issue=3 |pages=[https://edisciplinas.usp.br/pluginfile.php/262957/mod_resource/content/2/Iannaccone%20-%20Economics%20of%20Religion.pdf 1465–1495.]}}<br />&nbsp;• Anderson, Gary M. (1988). "Mr. Smith and the Preachers: The Economics of Religion in the Wealth of Nations," ''Journal of Political Economy'', '''96'''(5), [http://www.jstor.org/stable/1837247 pp. 1066–1088.]</ref>

[[Image:Religion economy.png|thumb|550px|The average annual income of countries correlates negatively [[Importance of religion by country|with national levels of religiosity]].<ref name=WIN-Gallup>{{cite web|last=WIN-Gallup|title=Global Index of religion and atheism.|url=http://redcresearch.ie/wp-content/uploads/2012/08/RED-C-press-release-Religion-and-Atheism-25-7-12.pdf|accessdate=21 October 2012}}</ref>]]



Empirical work examines the causal influence of religion in [[microeconomics]] to explain individual behaviour<ref>{{cite book |url= https://books.google.com/books?id=913O9xcpBB4C&q=starke+and+finke |title= Acts of Faith: Explaining the Human Side of Religion|isbn= 9780520222021|last1= Stark|first1= Rodney|last2= Finke|first2= Roger|date= August 2000|publisher= University of California Press}}</ref> and in the [[macroeconomic]] determinants of [[economic growth]].<ref>{{cite journal |last1= Barro |first1= Robert J. |last2= McCleary |first2= Rachel M. |title= Religion and Economic Growth across Countries |journal= American Sociological Review |date= 2003 |volume= 68 |issue= 5 |pages= 760–781 |doi= 10.2307/1519761 |jstor= 1519761|url= http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:3708464 }}</ref> '''Religious economics''' (or '''theological economics''') is a related subject sometimes{{quantify|date=October 2020}} overlapping or conflated with the economics of religion.<ref>For example, the [http://www.acton.org/pub/journal-markets-morality ''Journal of Markets & Morality''] of the [[Acton Institute for the Study of Religion and Liberty]] and [http://www.gordon.edu/ace/ACEFandE.html ''Faith & Economics''] of the Association of Christian Economists.<br />&nbsp;&nbsp;

The '''economics of religion''' applies [[social economics|socio-]] [[Economics|economic]] theory and [[economic methodology|methods]] to explain the [[religious behaviour]] patterns of individuals, groups or [[cultural economics|cultures]] and the social consequences of such behavior. An example of the first is [[Adam Smith]]'s analysis of the effect of [[competition (economics)|competition]] and government regulation (or support) for religious denominations on the quantity and quality of religious services.<ref>• Adam Smith, 1776 1904. ''[[Wealth of Nations]]'', [http://www.econlib.org/library/Smith/smWN20.html#B.V,%20Ch.1,%20Of%20the%20Expences%20of%20the%20Sovereign%20or%20Commonwealth Book V, Chapter I.]

• Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. ''Economics and Religion'', Elgar, v. 2, part II, Economics of Religion, scrollable [http://www.ecampus.com/book/9781840648492 table of contents], 10 of 41 papers, 1939–2002.<br />&nbsp;&nbsp;

• Patrick J. Welch and J.J. Mueller, 2001. "The Relationship of Religion to Economics," ''Review of Social Economy'', 59(2). pp. 185–202. [http://www3.baylor.edu/2002conference/abstracts/Welch,+Patrick+abstract.pdf Abstract.] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20060915193451/http://www3.baylor.edu/2002conference/abstracts/Welch%2C%20Patrick%20abstract.pdf |date=2006-09-15 }}<br />&nbsp;&nbsp;

• Paul Oslington, 2000. "A Theological Economics," ''International Journal of Social Economics'', 27(1), pp.[http://www.essaybay.com/articles/theology4.pdf \ 32–44.]<br />&nbsp;&nbsp;

• Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. ''Economics and Religion'', v. 1, Historical Relationships, table of contents, pp. v–vi with links via upper [https://books.google.com/books?id=PDgxjACbK8AC&pg=PP10 right-arrow] to Introduction and first 11 of 17 papers, 1939–2002.<br />&nbsp;&nbsp;

• Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. ''Economics and Religion'', v. 2, part I, Religious Economics and its Critics, scrollable [http://www.ecampus.com/book/9781840648492 table of contents], 14 papers, 1939–2002.<br />&nbsp;&nbsp;

• A.M.C. Waterman, 2002. "Economics as Theology: Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations," ''Southern Economic Journal'', 68(4), p [https://www.jstor.org/pss/1061499 pp. 907]–921. Reprinted in Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. Economics and Religion, v. 1, pp. [https://books.google.com/books?id=PDgxjACbK8AC&pg=PA321 321]–[https://books.google.com/books?id=PDgxjACbK8AC&pg=PA336 336.]<br />&nbsp;&nbsp;

• [[Thomas Nixon Carver]], 1908. "The Economic Basis of the Problem of Evil," ''Harvard Theological Review'', 1(1), pp. [https://books.google.com/books?id=lP0LAAAAIAAJ&dq=bl&pg=PA97 97]–[https://books.google.com/books?id=lP0LAAAAIAAJ&dq=bl&pg=PA111 111.]<br />&nbsp;&nbsp;

• _____, 1912. ''The Religion Worth Having''. Chapter [https://books.google.com/books?id=79AjG-BxewkC&q=%22 links.]<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • Mahmoud A. El-Gamal, 2006. ''Islamic Finance: Law, Economics, and Practice''. Cambridge. [https://web.archive.org/web/20060812051833/http://www.cambridge.org/us/catalogue/catalogue.asp?isbn=0521864143 Description and chapter titles.]</ref>



==History==

<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • Gary M. Anderson, 1988. "Mr. Smith and the Preachers: The Economics of Religion in the ''Wealth of Nations''," ''Journal of Political Economy'', 96(5), p [http://www.jstor.org/pss/1837247 p. 1066]-1088. Reprinted in Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. ''Economics and Religion'', Elgar, v. 1, pp. [http://books.google.com/books?hl=en&lr=&id=PDgxjACbK8AC&oi=fnd&pg=PA336&ots=jUcMdJuPuf&sig=kGPnD-pUaO7URku_AHU69laIk5Y#v=onepage&q=&f=fa 336]-[http://books.google.com/books?hl=en&lr=&id=PDgxjACbK8AC&oi=fnd&pg=PA358&ots=jUcMdJuPuf&sig=kGPnD-pUaO7URku_AHU69laIk5Y#v=onepage&q=&f=true 358.]</ref> An example of the second is [[Max Weber]]'s thesis that the [[Max Weber#The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism|Protestant ethic]] promoted the rise of [[capitalism]].<ref>• Max Weber, [1904] 1920. ''[[The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism]]''.<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • Kurt Samuelsson, [1957] 1964. ''Religion and Economic Action: A Critique of Max Weber''. 1-page chapter-preview [http://www.questia.com/PM.qst?a=o&d=691417 links.]<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • Jacques Delacroix and François Nielsen, 2001. "The Beloved Myth: Protestantism and the Rise of Industrial Capitalism in Nineteenth-Century Europe," ''Social Forces'', 80(2), pp. [http://www.unc.edu/~nielsen/special/s7/sample_minion_2001.pdf 509-553] (press '''+''').</ref>

[[Adam Smith]] laid a foundation for economic analysis for religion in ''[[The Wealth of Nations]]'' (1776), stating that religious organisations are subject to [[market forces]], [[incentive]] and [[competition]] problems like any other [[sectors of the economy|sector of the economy]].<ref>{{cite book |last1= Smith |first1= Adam |title= The Wealth of Nations |date= 1776 |publisher= Methuen & Co |location=London |page= 749}}</ref>{{request quotation|date=October 2020}}<ref>

Compare:

{{cite book

| last1 = Smith

| first1 = Adam

| author-link1 = Adam Smith

| chapter = Book V: Of the Revenue of the Sovereign or Commonwealth; Chapter 1: Of the Expences of the Sovereign or Commonwealth

| title = An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations

| year = 1776

| url = https://books.google.com/books?id=lYNaAAAAYAAJ

| volume = 2

| location = London

| publisher = Whitestone

| publication-date = 1776

| pages = 406–407

| access-date = 10 October 2020

| quote = The revenue of every established church [...] is a branch [...] of the general revenues of the state, which is thus diverted to purpose very different from the defence of the state. The tythe, for example, is a real land-tax [...]. The more of this fund that is given to the church, the less, it is evident, can be spared to the state. [...] all other things being supposed equal, the richer the church, the poorer must necessarily be, either the sovereign on the one hand, or the people on the other [...].

}}

</ref> [[Max Weber]] later identified a relationship between religion and economic behaviour, attributing in 1905 the modern advent of [[capitalism]] to the [[Protestant reformation]].<ref>{{cite book |last1= Weber |first1= Max |title= The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism | orig-year = 1905 |date= 2012 |publisher= Courier Corporation |isbn= 9780486122373 |url= https://books.google.com/books?id=ez7CAgAAQBAJ&q=weber+spirit+of++capitalism |language= en}}</ref>



==Religion and individual behaviour==

Religious (or theological) economics is a related subject sometimes overlapping or conflated with the economics of religion. It uses religious principles to evaluate economic perspectives or vice versa.<ref>For example, the [http://www.acton.org/pub/journal-markets-morality ''Journal of Markets & Morality''] of the Acton Institute for the Study of Religion and Liberty and [http://www.gordon.edu/ace/ACEFandE.html ''Faith & Economics''] of the Association of Christian Economists.<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. ''Economics and Religion'', Elgar, v. 2, part II, Economics of Religion, scrollable [http://www.ecampus.com/book/9781840648492 table of contents], 10 of 41 papers, 1939-2002.<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • Patrick J. Welch and J.J. Mueller, 2001. "The Relationship of Religion to Economics," ''Review of Social Economy'', 59(2). pp. 185-202. [https://web.archive.org/web/20030327010812/http://www3.baylor.edu/2002conference/abstracts/Welch,+Patrick+abstract.pdf Abstract.]<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • Paul Oslington, 2000. "A Theological Economics," ''International Journal of Social Economics'', 27(1), pp.[http://www.essaybay.com/articles/theology4.pdf \ 32-44.]<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. ''Economics and Religion'', v. 1, Historical Relationships, table of contents, pp. v-vi with links via upper [http://books.google.com/books?id=PDgxjACbK8AC&pg=PP10&lpg=PP7&ots=jUcI7NuNsm&lr= right-arrow] to Introduction and first 11 of 17 papers, 1939-2002.<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. ''Economics and Religion'', v. 2, part I, Religious Economics and its Critics, scrollable [http://www.ecampus.com/book/9781840648492 table of contents], 14 papers, 1939-2002.<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • A.M.C. Waterman, 2002. "Economics as Theology: Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations," ''Southern Economic Journal'', 68(4), p [http://www.jstor.org/pss/1061499 p. 907]-921. Reprinted in Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. Economics and Religion, v. 1, pp. [http://books.google.com/books?hl=en&lr=&id=PDgxjACbK8AC&oi=fnd&pg=PA321&ots=jUcMdJuPuf&sig=kGPnD-pUaO7URku_AHU69laIk5Y#v=onepage&q=&f=true 321]-[http://books.google.com/books?hl=en&lr=&id=PDgxjACbK8AC&oi=fnd&pg=PA336&ots=jUcMdJuPuf&sig=kGPnD-pUaO7URku_AHU69laIk5Y#v=onepage&q=&f=true 336.]<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • [[Thomas Nixon Carver]], 1908. "The Economic Basis of the Problem of Evil," ''Harvard Theological Review'', 1(1), pp. [http://books.google.com/books?id=lP0LAAAAIAAJ&pg=PA97&lpg=PA97&dq=bl&ots=d_S53v307b&sig=SdakU_iXyhn7XT-d-zbNYFUSB_Y&hl=en&ei=TGu6ScDVCuH8tgfa7eTiDw&sa=X&oi=book_result&resnum=2&ct=result 97]-[http://books.google.com/books?id=lP0LAAAAIAAJ&pg=PA111&lpg=PA111&dq=bl&ots=d_S53v307b&sig=SdakU_iXyhn7XT-d-zbNYFUSB_Y&hl=en&ei=TGu6ScDVCuH8tgfa7eTiDw&sa=X&oi=book_result&resnum=2&ct=result 111.]<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • _____, 1912. ''The Religion Worth Having''. Chapter [http://books.google.com/books?id=79AjG-BxewkC&dq=%22&printsec=frontcover&source=bl&ots=_vvfCP6Bnc&sig=M7nJT7b7-eQeYGA_f51G_GGWbyY&hl=en&ei=uu23SeeBNJjAtgfOwvGzCQ&sa=X&oi=book_result&resnum=1&ct=result#PPP9,M1 links.]<br />&nbsp;&nbsp; • Mahmoud A. El-Gamal, 2006. ''Islamic Finance: Law, Economics, and Practice''. Cambridge. [http://www.cambridge.org/us/catalogue/catalogue.asp?isbn=0521864143 Description and chapter titles.]</ref>

Research highlights the importance of [[Orthodoxy|religious orthodoxy]] on moral behaviours and versions of the [[Golden Rule]] “Do unto others as you would have others do unto you” are common to most major religions.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Batson |first1=Charles Daniel |last2=Schoenrade |first2=Patricia |last3=Ventis |first3=W. Larry |title=Religion and the Individual: A Social-Psychological Perspective |date=1993 |publisher=Oxford University Press |isbn=9780195062083 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=L58jAAAAYAAJ&q=batson+1993+religion+and+morality |language=en}}</ref> Others argue it promotes cooperation and trust within culturally defined groups or [[Club good|clubs]].<ref name="Iannaccone"/> Studies compare the complementary effects of religious values such as charity, forgiveness, honesty and tolerance and religious social groups where membership instils favouritism or discrimination towards in or outgroup members.<ref>{{cite journal |title=Cooperation and the in-group-out-group bias: A field test on Israeli kibbutz members and city residents |journal=Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization |date=1 June 2006 |volume=60 |issue=2 |pages=147–163 |doi=10.1016/j.jebo.2004.07.007 |language=en |issn=0167-2681|last1=Ruffle |first1=Bradley J. |last2=Sosis |first2=Richard |citeseerx=10.1.1.740.7036 |s2cid=15402779 }}</ref>


===Believing===

The believing channel of religion behaviours concerns costly effort concerned with divine reputation. Azzi and Ehrenberg (1975) propose individuals allocate time and money to secular and religious institutions to maximise utility in this life and the afterlife.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Azzi |first1=Corry |last2=Ehrenberg |first2=Ronald |title=Household Allocation of Time and Church Attendance |journal=Journal of Political Economy |date=February 1975 |volume=83 |issue=1 |pages=27–56 |doi=10.1086/260305 |s2cid=153985044 |language=en |issn=0022-3808|url=http://digitalcommons.ilr.cornell.edu/articles/633 |hdl=1813/75631 |hdl-access=free }}</ref> The colonisation of religious minds by the morally concerned supernatural or “Big Gods”<ref>{{cite book |last1=Norenzayan |first1=Ara |title=Big Gods: How Religion Transformed Cooperation and Conflict |date=2013 |publisher=Princeton University Press |isbn=978-1400848324 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=2VMtfYiQCXEC&q=big+gods |language=en}}</ref> diffused behaviours derived from moral instruction.


===Belonging===

The belonging approach to religion considers the social notion of between and within religious groups. Iannaconne (1998) assigns religion as a '[[club good]]' from a [[rational choice]] perspective where costly rituals exclude [[Free-rider problem|free-riders]] from in-group benefits. Field experiments also evidence religious people are more trusting and cooperative with fellow religious adherents. Many experimental studies suggest group belonging has a greater influence on behaviour than belief orthodoxy.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Hougland |first1=James G. |last2=Wood |first2=James R. |title=Control in Organizations and the Commitment of Members |journal=Social Forces |date=1980 |volume=59 |issue=1 |pages=85–105 |doi=10.2307/2577834 |jstor=2577834}}</ref> As Darwin (1874) among others argue, the promotion of cooperative in-group behaviours is not unique to religious networks.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Becker |first1=Penny Edgell |last2=Dhingra |first2=Pawan H. |title=Religious Involvement and Volunteering: Implications for Civil Society |journal=Sociology of Religion |date=2001 |volume=62 |issue=3 |pages=315–335 |doi=10.2307/3712353 |jstor=3712353}}</ref>


==Experimental economics of religion==


Experimental methods can be applied to isolate the effect of religion on behaviour patterns and to distinguish between believing versus belonging channels. Experimental methods are useful in the economics of religion to standardise measurement and identify causal effect.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Hoffmann |first1=Robert |title=The Experimental Economics of Religion |journal=Journal of Economic Surveys |date=January 2012 |volume=27 |issue=5 |pages=813–845 |doi=10.1111/j.1467-6419.2011.00716.x |language=en |issn=0950-0804|citeseerx=10.1.1.227.6634 |s2cid=145765803 }}</ref> Methods include looking at religion in various games – [[Prisoner's dilemma]], [[public goods game]], [[ultimatum game]], [[dictator game]] and [[Choice under uncertainty|parametric choice]]. Generally, as Hoffman's (2011) survey shows, few statistically significant results have been identified which commentators attribute to opposing positive versus negative effects between and within individuals.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Obadia |first1=Lionel |last2=Wood |first2=Donald C. |title=Economics of Religion: Anthropological Approaches |date=2011 |publisher=Emerald Group Publishing |isbn=9781780522296 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=8KCmbdDlByMC&q=anthropological+approaches+to+religion |language=en}}</ref>


==Religion and economic growth==

[[Image:Religion economy.png|thumb|550px|The average annual income of countries correlates negatively [[Importance of religion by country|with national levels of religiosity]].<ref name=WIN-Gallup>{{cite web|last=WIN-Gallup |title=Global Index of religion and atheism. |url=http://redcresearch.ie/wp-content/uploads/2012/08/RED-C-press-release-Religion-and-Atheism-25-7-12.pdf |access-date=21 October 2012 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121016062403/http://redcresearch.ie/wp-content/uploads/2012/08/RED-C-press-release-Religion-and-Atheism-25-7-12.pdf |archive-date=16 October 2012 }}</ref>]]


''Effects of religion on economic outcomes''


Studies suggest there is a channel from religious behaviours to macroeconomic outcomes of economic growth, crime rates and institutional development.<ref>{{cite journal |title=People's opium? Religion and economic attitudes |journal=Journal of Monetary Economics |date=1 January 2003 |volume=50 |issue=1 |pages=225–282 |doi=10.1016/S0304-3932(02)00202-7 |language=en |issn=0304-3932|last1=Guiso |first1=Luigi |last2=Sapienza |first2=Paola |last3=Zingales |first3=Luigi |citeseerx=10.1.1.194.9800 |s2cid=157112771 }}</ref> Scholars hypothesise religion impacts economic outcomes through religious doctrines promoting thrift, work ethic, honesty and trust.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Barro |first1=Robert J. |last2=McCleary |first2=Rachel M. |title=Religion and Economic Growth across Countries |journal=American Sociological Review |date=2003 |volume=68 |issue=5 |pages=760–781 |doi=10.2307/1519761 |jstor=1519761|url=http://nrs.harvard.edu/urn-3:HUL.InstRepos:3708464 }}</ref> These channels were described by [[Max Weber]] in his work [[The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism]]. Weber indicates that [[Protestantism|Protestant]] teachings were an important force behind the transition to modern day capitalism in Europe.<ref>Weber, M. (2002). The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism: and other writings. Penguin.</ref> Other studies highlight the effects of religion on [[human capital]] formation as the main mechanism behind the dependency. Human capital formation is driven by higher religious importance of literacy <ref name="Becker, S. O. 2009">Becker, S. O., & Woessmann, L. (2009). Was Weber wrong? A human capital theory of Protestant economic history. The quarterly journal of economics, 124(2), 531-596.</ref>


''Effects of economic outcomes on religion''


Studies indicate a two-way interaction between economic growth and religion. [[Secularization]] theory predicts that economic development reduces religious participation.<ref>McCleary, R. M., & Barro, R. J. (2006). Religion and economy. Journal of Economic perspectives, 20(2), 49-72.</ref> The empirical evidence in favour of this relationship is mixed.<ref>Buser, T. (2015). The effect of income on religiousness. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 7(3), 178-195.</ref><ref>Becker, S. O., & Woessmann, L. (2013). Not the opium of the people: Income and secularization in a panel of Prussian counties. American Economic Review, 103(3), 539-544.</ref>


=== Historical aspects ===

Religion can have long-lasting effects on a society and its economy. For instance, municipalities of Spain with a history of a stronger inquisitorial presence show lower economic performance and educational attainment today.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Drelichman|first1=Mauricio|last2=Vidal-Robert|first2=Jordi|last3=Voth|first3=Hans-Joachim|date=2021-08-17|title=The long-run effects of religious persecution: Evidence from the Spanish Inquisition|journal=Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences|language=en|volume=118|issue=33|pages=e2022881118|doi=10.1073/pnas.2022881118|issn=0027-8424|pmid=34389666|pmc=8379970|doi-access=free }}</ref> Similarly, Protestantism in Germany has long affected education and thus economic performance. In 1816, school attendance was about 50% in catholic regions while it was about 66% in Protestant regions.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Wößmann|first=Ludger|date=2017-10-12|title=Sind Protestanten schlauer?|url=https://www.zeit.de/2017/42/martin-luther-lutherjahr-protestanten-reformation-bildung/|url-status=live|access-date=2021-08-17|website=Zeit.de|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171015232611/http://www.zeit.de/2017/42/martin-luther-lutherjahr-protestanten-reformation-bildung |archive-date=2017-10-15 }}</ref> Higher literacy rates of Protestants can be observed in the 1870s/1880s in Prussia. It can be caused by the fact, that Martin Luther favoured Christians reading the Bible by themselves <ref name="Becker, S. O. 2009"/> Elements of Protestant ethic described by [[Max Weber|Weber]] and economic prosperity may have emerged before the [[Reformation]]. In case of England, regions that were exposed to [[Cistercians|Cistercian monasteries]] experienced a faster productivity growth from the 13th century onwards. The cultural influence was persistent even after the monasteries were dissolved. Modern attitudes towards hard work are positively related with influence of the Cistercians in the region.<ref>Andersen, T. B., Bentzen, J., Dalgaard, C. J., & Sharp, P. (2017). Pre‐reformation roots of the protestant ethic. The Economic Journal, 127(604), 1756-1793.</ref>


===Criticisms===

The correlation between religion and economic outcomes can be interpreted in two ways: (1) a feature intrinsic to religion which affects growth or (2) a feature correlated to religion but not religion itself which affects growth. Existing cross-country literature is criticised for inability to distinguish between the two explanations, a problem termed [[Endogeneity (econometrics)|endogeneity bias]]. Controlling for country [[fixed effects]] mitigates bias but more recent studies utilise field and natural experiments to identify the causal effect of religion.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Iyer |first1=Sriya |title=The New Economics of Religion |journal=Journal of Economic Literature |date=June 2016 |volume=54 |issue=2 |pages=395–441 |url=https://www.repository.cam.ac.uk/bitstream/handle/1810/255321/cwpe1544.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y|doi=10.1257/jel.54.2.395 |s2cid=38991072 }}</ref> Robustness of cross-country results to changes in specification of the statistical models is criticised in the literature.<ref>Durlauf, S. N., Kourtellos, A., & Tan, C. M. (2012). Is God in the details? A reexamination of the role of religion in economic growth. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 27(7), 1059-1075.</ref>



==See also==

==See also==

* [[Christian views on poverty and wealth]]

* [[Buddhist economics]]

* [[Buddhist economics]]

* [[Cultural economics]]

* [[Islamic economics]]

* [[Economic imperialism (economics)]]

* [[Institutional economics]]

* [[New institutional economics]]

* Pars pro toto principle

* [[Religion and business]]

* [[Religion and business]]

* [[Sociology of religion]]

* [[Sociology of religion]]

* [[Religious economy (disambiguation)|Religious economy]]

* [[Wealth and religion]]

* [[Islamic economics in the world]]

* [[Religiosity and intelligence]]

* [[Religiosity and intelligence]]

* [[Wealth and religion]]


'''Books:'''

* ''[[Malaysia and the Club of Doom]]''



==References==

==References==

{{reflist|colwidth=30em}}

{{Reflist|colwidth=30em}}



==External links==

==External links==

* [https://web.archive.org/web/20100605103050/http://www.religionomics.com/index.html Economics of Religion Gateway:] "What is the economic study of religion?" from the [https://web.archive.org/web/20100205101515/http://www.religionomics.com/asrec/index.html Association for the Study of Religion, Economics, and Culture.]

* [http://content.time.com/time/magazine/article/0,9171,1533448,00.html Does God Want You To Be Rich?]

* [https://web.archive.org/web/20110726031920/http://www.ener-online.org/about.html European Network on the Economics of Religion]

* [http://www.religionomics.com/index.html Economics of Religion Gateway:] "What is the economic study of religion?" from the [http://www.religionomics.com/asrec/index.html Association for the Study of Religion, Economics, and Culture.]

* [https://web.archive.org/web/20041210032955/http://www.businessweek.com/magazine/content/04_49/b3911107_mz057.htm "Economists Are Getting Religion,"] ''Business Week''

* [http://www.ener-online.org/about.html European Network on the Economics of Religion]

* [https://web.archive.org/web/20090417021330/http://www.religionlink.org/tip_050131b.php "The economics of religion"]

* [http://www.businessweek.com/magazine/content/04_49/b3911107_mz057.htm "Economists Are Getting Religion,"] ''Business Week''


* [http://www.religionlink.org/tip_050131b.php "The economics of religion"]

{{Authority control}}



{{DEFAULTSORT:Economics Of Religion}}

{{DEFAULTSORT:Economics Of Religion}}

[[Category:Economics of religion|*]]

[[Category:Economy and religion| ]]


Latest revision as of 06:36, 23 February 2024

The economics of religion concerns both the application of the techniques of economics to the study of religion and the relationship between economic and religious behaviours.[1][2] Contemporary writers on the subject trace it back to Adam Smith (1776).[3]

Empirical work examines the causal influence of religion in microeconomics to explain individual behaviour[4] and in the macroeconomic determinants of economic growth.[5] Religious economics (ortheological economics) is a related subject sometimes[quantify] overlapping or conflated with the economics of religion.[6]

History[edit]

Adam Smith laid a foundation for economic analysis for religion in The Wealth of Nations (1776), stating that religious organisations are subject to market forces, incentive and competition problems like any other sector of the economy.[7][need quotation to verify][8] Max Weber later identified a relationship between religion and economic behaviour, attributing in 1905 the modern advent of capitalism to the Protestant reformation.[9]

Religion and individual behaviour[edit]

Research highlights the importance of religious orthodoxy on moral behaviours and versions of the Golden Rule “Do unto others as you would have others do unto you” are common to most major religions.[10] Others argue it promotes cooperation and trust within culturally defined groups or clubs.[1] Studies compare the complementary effects of religious values such as charity, forgiveness, honesty and tolerance and religious social groups where membership instils favouritism or discrimination towards in or outgroup members.[11]

Believing[edit]

The believing channel of religion behaviours concerns costly effort concerned with divine reputation. Azzi and Ehrenberg (1975) propose individuals allocate time and money to secular and religious institutions to maximise utility in this life and the afterlife.[12] The colonisation of religious minds by the morally concerned supernatural or “Big Gods”[13] diffused behaviours derived from moral instruction.

Belonging[edit]

The belonging approach to religion considers the social notion of between and within religious groups. Iannaconne (1998) assigns religion as a 'club good' from a rational choice perspective where costly rituals exclude free-riders from in-group benefits. Field experiments also evidence religious people are more trusting and cooperative with fellow religious adherents. Many experimental studies suggest group belonging has a greater influence on behaviour than belief orthodoxy.[14] As Darwin (1874) among others argue, the promotion of cooperative in-group behaviours is not unique to religious networks.[15]

Experimental economics of religion[edit]

Experimental methods can be applied to isolate the effect of religion on behaviour patterns and to distinguish between believing versus belonging channels. Experimental methods are useful in the economics of religion to standardise measurement and identify causal effect.[16] Methods include looking at religion in various games – Prisoner's dilemma, public goods game, ultimatum game, dictator game and parametric choice. Generally, as Hoffman's (2011) survey shows, few statistically significant results have been identified which commentators attribute to opposing positive versus negative effects between and within individuals.[17]

Religion and economic growth[edit]

The average annual income of countries correlates negatively with national levels of religiosity.[18]

Effects of religion on economic outcomes

Studies suggest there is a channel from religious behaviours to macroeconomic outcomes of economic growth, crime rates and institutional development.[19] Scholars hypothesise religion impacts economic outcomes through religious doctrines promoting thrift, work ethic, honesty and trust.[20] These channels were described by Max Weber in his work The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. Weber indicates that Protestant teachings were an important force behind the transition to modern day capitalism in Europe.[21] Other studies highlight the effects of religion on human capital formation as the main mechanism behind the dependency. Human capital formation is driven by higher religious importance of literacy [22]

Effects of economic outcomes on religion

Studies indicate a two-way interaction between economic growth and religion. Secularization theory predicts that economic development reduces religious participation.[23] The empirical evidence in favour of this relationship is mixed.[24][25]

Historical aspects[edit]

Religion can have long-lasting effects on a society and its economy. For instance, municipalities of Spain with a history of a stronger inquisitorial presence show lower economic performance and educational attainment today.[26] Similarly, Protestantism in Germany has long affected education and thus economic performance. In 1816, school attendance was about 50% in catholic regions while it was about 66% in Protestant regions.[27] Higher literacy rates of Protestants can be observed in the 1870s/1880s in Prussia. It can be caused by the fact, that Martin Luther favoured Christians reading the Bible by themselves [22] Elements of Protestant ethic described by Weber and economic prosperity may have emerged before the Reformation. In case of England, regions that were exposed to Cistercian monasteries experienced a faster productivity growth from the 13th century onwards. The cultural influence was persistent even after the monasteries were dissolved. Modern attitudes towards hard work are positively related with influence of the Cistercians in the region.[28]

Criticisms[edit]

The correlation between religion and economic outcomes can be interpreted in two ways: (1) a feature intrinsic to religion which affects growth or (2) a feature correlated to religion but not religion itself which affects growth. Existing cross-country literature is criticised for inability to distinguish between the two explanations, a problem termed endogeneity bias. Controlling for country fixed effects mitigates bias but more recent studies utilise field and natural experiments to identify the causal effect of religion.[29] Robustness of cross-country results to changes in specification of the statistical models is criticised in the literature.[30]

See also[edit]

References[edit]

  1. ^ a b Iannaccone, Laurence R. (1998). "Introduction to the Economics of Religion". Journal of Economic Literature. 36 (3): pp.1465–1495.
  • ^ McCleary, Rachel M. (2011). The Oxford Handbook of the Economics of Religion. Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780199781287.
  • ^ Iannaccone, Laurence R. (1998). "Introduction to the Economics of Religion". Journal of Economic Literature. 36 (3): 1465–1495.
     • Anderson, Gary M. (1988). "Mr. Smith and the Preachers: The Economics of Religion in the Wealth of Nations," Journal of Political Economy, 96(5), pp. 1066–1088.
  • ^ Stark, Rodney; Finke, Roger (August 2000). Acts of Faith: Explaining the Human Side of Religion. University of California Press. ISBN 9780520222021.
  • ^ Barro, Robert J.; McCleary, Rachel M. (2003). "Religion and Economic Growth across Countries". American Sociological Review. 68 (5): 760–781. doi:10.2307/1519761. JSTOR 1519761.
  • ^ For example, the Journal of Markets & Morality of the Acton Institute for the Study of Religion and Liberty and Faith & Economics of the Association of Christian Economists.
       • Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. Economics and Religion, Elgar, v. 2, part II, Economics of Religion, scrollable table of contents, 10 of 41 papers, 1939–2002.
       • Patrick J. Welch and J.J. Mueller, 2001. "The Relationship of Religion to Economics," Review of Social Economy, 59(2). pp. 185–202. Abstract. Archived 2006-09-15 at the Wayback Machine
       • Paul Oslington, 2000. "A Theological Economics," International Journal of Social Economics, 27(1), pp.\ 32–44.
       • Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. Economics and Religion, v. 1, Historical Relationships, table of contents, pp. v–vi with links via upper right-arrow to Introduction and first 11 of 17 papers, 1939–2002.
       • Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. Economics and Religion, v. 2, part I, Religious Economics and its Critics, scrollable table of contents, 14 papers, 1939–2002.
       • A.M.C. Waterman, 2002. "Economics as Theology: Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations," Southern Economic Journal, 68(4), p pp. 907–921. Reprinted in Paul Oslington, ed., 2003. Economics and Religion, v. 1, pp. 321336.
       • Thomas Nixon Carver, 1908. "The Economic Basis of the Problem of Evil," Harvard Theological Review, 1(1), pp. 97111.
       • _____, 1912. The Religion Worth Having. Chapter links.
       • Mahmoud A. El-Gamal, 2006. Islamic Finance: Law, Economics, and Practice. Cambridge. Description and chapter titles.
  • ^ Smith, Adam (1776). The Wealth of Nations. London: Methuen & Co. p. 749.
  • ^ Compare: Smith, Adam (1776). "Book V: Of the Revenue of the Sovereign or Commonwealth; Chapter 1: Of the Expences of the Sovereign or Commonwealth". An Inquiry Into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Vol. 2. London: Whitestone. pp. 406–407. Retrieved 10 October 2020. The revenue of every established church [...] is a branch [...] of the general revenues of the state, which is thus diverted to purpose very different from the defence of the state. The tythe, for example, is a real land-tax [...]. The more of this fund that is given to the church, the less, it is evident, can be spared to the state. [...] all other things being supposed equal, the richer the church, the poorer must necessarily be, either the sovereign on the one hand, or the people on the other [...].
  • ^ Weber, Max (2012) [1905]. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. Courier Corporation. ISBN 9780486122373.
  • ^ Batson, Charles Daniel; Schoenrade, Patricia; Ventis, W. Larry (1993). Religion and the Individual: A Social-Psychological Perspective. Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780195062083.
  • ^ Ruffle, Bradley J.; Sosis, Richard (1 June 2006). "Cooperation and the in-group-out-group bias: A field test on Israeli kibbutz members and city residents". Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization. 60 (2): 147–163. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.740.7036. doi:10.1016/j.jebo.2004.07.007. ISSN 0167-2681. S2CID 15402779.
  • ^ Azzi, Corry; Ehrenberg, Ronald (February 1975). "Household Allocation of Time and Church Attendance". Journal of Political Economy. 83 (1): 27–56. doi:10.1086/260305. hdl:1813/75631. ISSN 0022-3808. S2CID 153985044.
  • ^ Norenzayan, Ara (2013). Big Gods: How Religion Transformed Cooperation and Conflict. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-1400848324.
  • ^ Hougland, James G.; Wood, James R. (1980). "Control in Organizations and the Commitment of Members". Social Forces. 59 (1): 85–105. doi:10.2307/2577834. JSTOR 2577834.
  • ^ Becker, Penny Edgell; Dhingra, Pawan H. (2001). "Religious Involvement and Volunteering: Implications for Civil Society". Sociology of Religion. 62 (3): 315–335. doi:10.2307/3712353. JSTOR 3712353.
  • ^ Hoffmann, Robert (January 2012). "The Experimental Economics of Religion". Journal of Economic Surveys. 27 (5): 813–845. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.227.6634. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6419.2011.00716.x. ISSN 0950-0804. S2CID 145765803.
  • ^ Obadia, Lionel; Wood, Donald C. (2011). Economics of Religion: Anthropological Approaches. Emerald Group Publishing. ISBN 9781780522296.
  • ^ WIN-Gallup. "Global Index of religion and atheism" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 16 October 2012. Retrieved 21 October 2012.
  • ^ Guiso, Luigi; Sapienza, Paola; Zingales, Luigi (1 January 2003). "People's opium? Religion and economic attitudes". Journal of Monetary Economics. 50 (1): 225–282. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.194.9800. doi:10.1016/S0304-3932(02)00202-7. ISSN 0304-3932. S2CID 157112771.
  • ^ Barro, Robert J.; McCleary, Rachel M. (2003). "Religion and Economic Growth across Countries". American Sociological Review. 68 (5): 760–781. doi:10.2307/1519761. JSTOR 1519761.
  • ^ Weber, M. (2002). The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism: and other writings. Penguin.
  • ^ a b Becker, S. O., & Woessmann, L. (2009). Was Weber wrong? A human capital theory of Protestant economic history. The quarterly journal of economics, 124(2), 531-596.
  • ^ McCleary, R. M., & Barro, R. J. (2006). Religion and economy. Journal of Economic perspectives, 20(2), 49-72.
  • ^ Buser, T. (2015). The effect of income on religiousness. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 7(3), 178-195.
  • ^ Becker, S. O., & Woessmann, L. (2013). Not the opium of the people: Income and secularization in a panel of Prussian counties. American Economic Review, 103(3), 539-544.
  • ^ Drelichman, Mauricio; Vidal-Robert, Jordi; Voth, Hans-Joachim (2021-08-17). "The long-run effects of religious persecution: Evidence from the Spanish Inquisition". Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 118 (33): e2022881118. doi:10.1073/pnas.2022881118. ISSN 0027-8424. PMC 8379970. PMID 34389666.
  • ^ Wößmann, Ludger (2017-10-12). "Sind Protestanten schlauer?". Zeit.de. Archived from the original on 2017-10-15. Retrieved 2021-08-17.
  • ^ Andersen, T. B., Bentzen, J., Dalgaard, C. J., & Sharp, P. (2017). Pre‐reformation roots of the protestant ethic. The Economic Journal, 127(604), 1756-1793.
  • ^ Iyer, Sriya (June 2016). "The New Economics of Religion" (PDF). Journal of Economic Literature. 54 (2): 395–441. doi:10.1257/jel.54.2.395. S2CID 38991072.
  • ^ Durlauf, S. N., Kourtellos, A., & Tan, C. M. (2012). Is God in the details? A reexamination of the role of religion in economic growth. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 27(7), 1059-1075.
  • External links[edit]


    Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Economics_of_religion&oldid=1209713655"

    Category: 
    Economy and religion
    Hidden categories: 
    Webarchive template wayback links
    All articles with unsourced statements
    Articles with unsourced statements from October 2020
    Wikipedia articles needing factual verification from October 2020
    Articles with J9U identifiers
    Articles with LCCN identifiers
    Articles with NKC identifiers
     



    This page was last edited on 23 February 2024, at 06:36 (UTC).

    Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License 4.0; additional terms may apply. By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., a non-profit organization.



    Privacy policy

    About Wikipedia

    Disclaimers

    Contact Wikipedia

    Code of Conduct

    Developers

    Statistics

    Cookie statement

    Mobile view



    Wikimedia Foundation
    Powered by MediaWiki