Jump to content
 







Main menu
   


Navigation  



Main page
Contents
Current events
Random article
About Wikipedia
Contact us
Donate
 




Contribute  



Help
Learn to edit
Community portal
Recent changes
Upload file
 








Search  

































Create account

Log in
 









Create account
 Log in
 




Pages for logged out editors learn more  



Contributions
Talk
 



















Contents

   



(Top)
 


1 Examples  





2 Perfect complement  



2.1  Example  







3 Gross complements  



3.1  Proof  







4 Effect of price change of complementary goods  





5 References  














Complementary good






Чӑвашла
Čeština
Deutsch
Español
فارسی

Հայերեն
ि
עברית

Lietuvių
Nederlands

Norsk bokmål
Polski
Português
Română
Русский
Simple English
ி

Українська


 

Edit links
 









Article
Talk
 

















Read
Edit
View history
 








Tools
   


Actions  



Read
Edit
View history
 




General  



What links here
Related changes
Upload file
Special pages
Permanent link
Page information
Cite this page
Get shortened URL
Download QR code
Wikidata item
 




Print/export  



Download as PDF
Printable version
 
















Appearance
   

 






From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
 

(Redirected from Complementary goods)

Complementary goods exhibit a negative cross elasticity of demand: as the price of goods Y rises, the demand for good X falls.

Ineconomics, a complementary good is a good whose appeal increases with the popularity of its complement.[further explanation needed] Technically, it displays a negative cross elasticity of demand and that demand for it increases when the price of another good decreases.[1]If is a complement to , an increase in the price of will result in a negative movement along the demand curve of and cause the demand curve for toshift inward; less of each good will be demanded. Conversely, a decrease in the price of will result in a positive movement along the demand curve of and cause the demand curve of toshift outward; more of each good will be demanded. This is in contrast to a substitute good, whose demand decreases when its substitute's price decreases.[2]

When two goods are complements, they experience joint demand - the demand of one good is linked to the demand for another good. Therefore, if a higher quantity is demanded of one good, a higher quantity will also be demanded of the other, and vice versa. For example, the demand for razor blades may depend on the number of razors in use; this is why razors have sometimes been sold as loss leaders, to increase demand for the associated blades.[3] Another example is that sometimes a toothbrush is packaged free with toothpaste. The toothbrush is a complement to the toothpaste; the cost of producing a toothbrush may be higher than toothpaste, but its sales depends on the demand of toothpaste.

All non-complementary goods can be considered substitutes.[4]If and are rough complements in an everyday sense, then consumers are willing to pay more for each marginal unit of good as they accumulate more . The opposite is true for substitutes: the consumer is willing to pay less for each marginal unit of good "" as it accumulates more of good "".

Complementarity may be driven by psychological processes in which the consumption of one good (e.g., cola) stimulates demand for its complements (e.g., a cheeseburger). Consumption of a food or beverage activates a goal to consume its complements: foods that consumers believe would taste better together. Drinking cola increases consumers' willingness to pay for a cheeseburger. This effect appears to be contingent on consumer perceptions of these relationships rather than their sensory properties.[5]

Examples[edit]

Supply and Demand curves.
Supply and demand of cars when the price of petrol decreases

An example of this would be the demand for cars and petrol. The supply and demand for cars is represented by the figure, with the initial demand . Suppose that the initial price of cars is represented by with a quantity demanded of . If the price of petrol were to decrease by some amount, this would result in a higher quantity of cars demanded. This higher quantity demanded would cause the demand curve to shift rightward to a new position . Assuming a constant supply curve of cars, the new increased quantity demanded will be at with a new increased price . Other examples include automobiles and fuel, mobile phones and cellular service, printer and cartridge, among others.

Perfect complement[edit]

Indifference curve for perfect complements

Aperfect complement is a good that must be consumed with another good. The indifference curve of a perfect complement exhibits a right angle, as illustrated by the figure.[6] Such preferences can be represented by a Leontief utility function.

Few goods behave as perfect complements.[6] One example is a left shoe and a right; shoes are naturally sold in pairs, and the ratio between sales of left and right shoes will never shift noticeably from 1:1.

The degree of complementarity, however, does not have to be mutual; it can be measured by the cross price elasticity of demand. In the case of video games, a specific video game (the complement good) has to be consumed with a video game console (the base good). It does not work the other way: a video game console does not have to be consumed with that game.

Example[edit]

Inmarketing, complementary goods give additional market power to the producer. It allows vendor lock-in by increasing switching costs. A few types of pricing strategy exist for a complementary good and its base good:

Gross complements[edit]

Sometimes the complement-relationship between two goods is not intuitive and must be verified by inspecting the cross-elasticity of demand using market data.

Mosak's definition states "a good is a gross complement of if is negative, where for denotes the ordinary individual demand for a certain good." In fact, in Mosak's case, is not a gross complement of but is a gross complement of . The elasticity does not need to be symmetrical. Thus, is a gross complement of while can simultaneously be a gross substitutes for .[7]

Proof[edit]

The standard Hicks decomposition of the effect on the ordinary demand for a good of a simple price change in a good , utility level and chosen bundle is

If is a gross substitute for , the left-hand side of the equation and the first term of right-hand side are positive. By the symmetry of Mosak's perspective, evaluating the equation with respect to , the first term of right-hand side stays the same while some extreme cases exist where is large enough to make the whole right-hand-side negative. In this case, is a gross complement of . Overall, and are not symmetrical.

Effect of price change of complementary goods[edit]

References[edit]

  1. ^ Carbaugh, Robert (2006). Contemporary Economics: An Applications Approach. Cengage Learning. p. 35. ISBN 978-0-324-31461-8.
  • ^ O'Sullivan, Arthur; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003). Economics: Principles in Action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey: Pearson Prentice Hall. p. 88. ISBN 0-13-063085-3.
  • ^ "Customer in Marketing by David Mercer". Future Observatory. Archived from the original on 2013-04-04.
  • ^ Newman, Peter (2016-11-30) [1987]. "Substitutes and Complements". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics: 1–7. doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_1821-1. ISBN 978-1-349-95121-5. Retrieved 2022-05-26.
  • ^ Huh, Young Eun; Vosgerau, Joachim; Morewedge, Carey K. (2016-03-14). "Selective Sensitization: Consuming a Food Activates a Goal to Consume its Complements". Journal of Marketing Research. 53 (6): 1034–1049. doi:10.1509/jmr.12.0240. ISSN 0022-2437. S2CID 4800997.
  • ^ a b Mankiw, Gregory (2008). Principle of Economics. Cengage Learning. pp. 463–464. ISBN 978-0-324-58997-9.
  • ^ Mosak, Jacob L. (1944). "General equilibrium theory in international trade" (PDF). Cowles Commission for Research in Economics, Monograph No. 7. Principia Press: 33.

  • Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Complementary_good&oldid=1228535287"

    Categories: 
    Goods (economics)
    Utility function types
    Hidden categories: 
    Articles with short description
    Short description is different from Wikidata
    Wikipedia articles needing clarification from October 2022
     



    This page was last edited on 11 June 2024, at 19:31 (UTC).

    Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License 4.0; additional terms may apply. By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., a non-profit organization.



    Privacy policy

    About Wikipedia

    Disclaimers

    Contact Wikipedia

    Code of Conduct

    Developers

    Statistics

    Cookie statement

    Mobile view



    Wikimedia Foundation
    Powered by MediaWiki