Jump to content
 







Main menu
   


Navigation  



Main page
Contents
Current events
Random article
About Wikipedia
Contact us
Donate
 




Contribute  



Help
Learn to edit
Community portal
Recent changes
Upload file
 








Search  

































Create account

Log in
 









Create account
 Log in
 




Pages for logged out editors learn more  



Contributions
Talk
 



















Contents

   



(Top)
 


1 Historical schools and factors  



1.1  Physiocracy  





1.2  Classical  





1.3  Marxism  





1.4  Neoclassical economics  





1.5  Ecological economics  







2 A fourth factor?  



2.1  Entrepreneurship  





2.2  Natural resources  





2.3  Energy  





2.4  Cultural heritage  







3 See also  





4 References  





5 Further reading  





6 External links  














Factors of production: Difference between revisions






Alemannisch
العربية
Azərbaycanca

Български
Català
Чӑвашла
Čeština
Dansk
Deutsch
Ελληνικά
Español
Euskara
فارسی
Français

Հայերեն
ि
Ido
Bahasa Indonesia
Íslenska
Italiano
עברית
Қазақша

Magyar
Македонски

Bahasa Melayu
Nederlands

Norsk bokmål
Polski
Português
Română
Русский
Shqip
Simple English
Slovenčina
Slovenščina
Српски / srpski
Suomi
Svenska
ி
Татарча / tatarça

Türkçe
Українська
اردو
Tiếng Vit


 

Edit links
 









Article
Talk
 

















Read
Edit
View history
 








Tools
   


Actions  



Read
Edit
View history
 




General  



What links here
Related changes
Upload file
Special pages
Permanent link
Page information
Cite this page
Get shortened URL
Download QR code
Wikidata item
 




Print/export  



Download as PDF
Printable version
 




Print/export  







In other projects  



Wikimedia Commons
 
















Appearance
   

 





Help
 

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
 


Browse history interactively
 Previous editNext edit 
Content deleted Content added
Corrected statement.
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
Corrected statement.
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit
Line 2: Line 2:

In [[economics]], '''factors of production''', '''resources''', or '''inputs''' are what is used in the production process to produce [[output (economics)|output]]—that is, finished goods and services. The utilized amounts of the various inputs determine the quantity of output according to the relationship called the [[production function]]. There are four ''basic'' resources or factors of Production: land, Labour, enterprise and Capital. The factors are also frequently labeled "producer goods or services" to distinguish them from the goods or services purchased by consumers, which are frequently labeled "consumer goods".

In [[economics]], '''factors of production''', '''resources''', or '''inputs''' are what is used in the production process to produce [[output (economics)|output]]—that is, finished goods and services. The utilized amounts of the various inputs determine the quantity of output according to the relationship called the [[production function]]. There are four ''basic'' resources or factors of Production: land, Labour, enterprise and Capital. The factors are also frequently labeled "producer goods or services" to distinguish them from the goods or services purchased by consumers, which are frequently labeled "consumer goods".



There are two types of factors: ''primary'' and ''secondary''. The previously mentioned primary factors are land, Labour, enterprise and Capital goods. Materials and energy are considered secondary factors in classical economics because they are obtained from land, labour, and capital. The primary factors facilitate production but neither becomes part of the product (as with [[raw material]]s) nor becomes significantly transformed by the production process (as with fuel used to power machinery). Land includes not only the site of production but also [[natural resource]]s above or below the soil. Recent usage has distinguished [[human capital]] (the stock of knowledge in the [[labor force]]) from labor.<ref>[[Paul A. Samuelson]] and [[William D. Nordhaus]] (2004). ''[[Economics (textbook)|Economics]]'', 18th ed., "Factors of production", "Capital", Human capital", and "Land" under Glossary of Terms.</ref> Entrepreneurship is also sometimes considered a factor of production.<ref>{{cite book| first2 = Steven M. |last2 = Sheffrin| last = O'Sullivan| first = Arthur| authorlink = Arthur O'Sullivan (economist) | title = Economics: Principles in Action| year = 2003| publisher = Pearson Prentice Hall| location = Upper Saddle River, New Jersey 07458| isbn = 978-0-13-063085-8| page = 4 }}</ref> Sometimes the overall state of [[technology]] is described as a factor of production.<ref>{{cite book |author1=Michael Parkin |author2=Gerardo Esquivel |title=Macroeconomía |location=Mexico |publisher=Addison Wesley |edition=5th |year=1999 |page=160 |isbn=968-444-441-9 |language=es}}</ref> The number and definition of factors vary, depending on theoretical purpose, empirical emphasis, or [[schools of economics|school of economics]].<ref>{{cite book| author = Milton Friedman| title = Price Theory| url = https://books.google.com/?id=BxaSUfPV2WkC&pg=PA201| year = 2007| publisher = Transaction Publishers| isbn = 978-0-202-30969-9| page = 201 }}</ref>

There are two types of factors: ''primary'' and ''secondary''. The previously mentioned primary factors are [[land (economics)|land]], [[Labour economics|labor]], and [[Capital (economics)|capital goods]].

Materials and energy are considered secondary factors in classical economics because they are obtained from land, labour, and capital. The primary factors facilitate production but neither becomes part of the product (as with [[raw material]]s) nor becomes significantly transformed by the production process (as with fuel used to power machinery). Land includes not only the site of production but also [[natural resource]]s above or below the soil. Recent usage has distinguished [[human capital]] (the stock of knowledge in the [[labor force]]) from labor.<ref>[[Paul A. Samuelson]] and [[William D. Nordhaus]] (2004). ''[[Economics (textbook)|Economics]]'', 18th ed., "Factors of production", "Capital", Human capital", and "Land" under Glossary of Terms.</ref> Entrepreneurship is also sometimes considered a factor of production.<ref>{{cite book| first2 = Steven M. |last2 = Sheffrin| last = O'Sullivan| first = Arthur| authorlink = Arthur O'Sullivan (economist) | title = Economics: Principles in Action| year = 2003| publisher = Pearson Prentice Hall| location = Upper Saddle River, New Jersey 07458| isbn = 978-0-13-063085-8| page = 4 }}</ref> Sometimes the overall state of [[technology]] is described as a factor of production.<ref>{{cite book |author1=Michael Parkin |author2=Gerardo Esquivel |title=Macroeconomía |location=Mexico |publisher=Addison Wesley |edition=5th |year=1999 |page=160 |isbn=968-444-441-9 |language=es}}</ref> The number and definition of factors vary, depending on theoretical purpose, empirical emphasis, or [[schools of economics|school of economics]].<ref>{{cite book| author = Milton Friedman| title = Price Theory| url = https://books.google.com/?id=BxaSUfPV2WkC&pg=PA201| year = 2007| publisher = Transaction Publishers| isbn = 978-0-202-30969-9| page = 201 }}</ref>



== Historical schools and factors ==

== Historical schools and factors ==


Revision as of 13:01, 4 November 2019

Ineconomics, factors of production, resources, or inputs are what is used in the production process to produce output—that is, finished goods and services. The utilized amounts of the various inputs determine the quantity of output according to the relationship called the production function. There are four basic resources or factors of Production: land, Labour, enterprise and Capital. The factors are also frequently labeled "producer goods or services" to distinguish them from the goods or services purchased by consumers, which are frequently labeled "consumer goods".

There are two types of factors: primary and secondary. The previously mentioned primary factors are land, Labour, enterprise and Capital goods. Materials and energy are considered secondary factors in classical economics because they are obtained from land, labour, and capital. The primary factors facilitate production but neither becomes part of the product (as with raw materials) nor becomes significantly transformed by the production process (as with fuel used to power machinery). Land includes not only the site of production but also natural resources above or below the soil. Recent usage has distinguished human capital (the stock of knowledge in the labor force) from labor.[1] Entrepreneurship is also sometimes considered a factor of production.[2] Sometimes the overall state of technology is described as a factor of production.[3] The number and definition of factors vary, depending on theoretical purpose, empirical emphasis, or school of economics.[4]

Historical schools and factors

In the interpretation of the currently dominant view of classical economic theory developed by neoclassical economists, the term "factors" did not exist until after the classical period and is not to be found in any of the literature of that time.[5]

Differences are most stark when it comes to deciding which factor is the most important.

Physiocracy

Physiocracy (from the Greek for "government of nature") is an economic theory developed by a group of 18th century Enlightenment French economists who believed that the wealth of nations was derived solely from the value of "land agriculture" or "land development" and that agricultural products should be highly priced

Classical

An advertisement for labor from Sabah and Sarawak seen in Jalan Petaling, Kuala Lumpur

The classical economicsofAdam Smith, David Ricardo, and their followers focus on physical resources in defining its factors of production and discuss the distribution of cost and value among these factors. Adam Smith and David Ricardo referred to the "component parts of price"[6] as the costs of using:

The classical economists also employed the word "capital" in reference to money. Money, however, was not considered to be a factor of production in the sense of capital stock since it is not used to directly produce any good.[7] The return to loaned money or to loaned stock was styled as interest while the return to the actual proprietor of capital stock (tools, etc.) was styled as profit. See also returns.

Marxism

Marx considered the "elementary factors of the labor-process" or "productive forces" to be:

The "subject of labor" refers to natural resources and raw materials, including land. The "instruments of labor" are tools, in the broadest sense. They include factory buildings, infrastructure, and other human-made objects that facilitate labor's production of goods and services.

This view seems similar to the classical perspective described above. But unlike the classical school and many economists today, Marx made a clear distinction between labor actually done and an individual's "labor power" or ability to work. Labor done is often referred to nowadays as "effort" or "labor services." Labor-power might be seen as a stock which can produce a flow of labor.

Labor, not labor power, is the key factor of production for Marx and the basis for Marx's labor theory of value. The hiring of labor power only results in the production of goods or services ("use-values") when organized and regulated (often by the "management"). How much labor is actually done depends on the importance of conflict or tensions within the labor process.

Neoclassical economics

Neoclassical economics, one of the branches of mainstream economics, started with the classical factors of production of land, labor, and capital. However, it developed an alternative theory of value and distribution. Many of its practitioners have added various further factors of production (see below).

Further distinctions from classical and neoclassical microeconomics include the following:

Ecological economics

Ecological economics is an alternative to neoclassical economics). It integrates, amongst other things, the first and second laws of thermodynamics (see: Laws of thermodynamics) to formulate more realistic economic systems that adhere to fundamental physical limitations. In addition to the neoclassical focus on efficient allocation, ecological economics emphasizes sustainability of scale and just distribution. Ecological economics also differ from neoclassical theories in its definitions of factors of production, replacing them with the following:[10][11]

Integral to ecological economics is the following notion: at the maximum rates of sustainable matter and energy uptake, the only way to increase productivity would be through an increase in design intelligence. This provides the basis for a core tenet of ecological economics, namely that infinite growth is impossible.[10]

A fourth factor?

As mentioned, recent authors have added to the classical list. For example, J. B. Clark saw the co-ordinating function in production and distribution as being served by entrepreneurs; Frank Knight introduced managers who co-ordinate using their own money (financial capital) and the financial capital of others. In contrast, many economists today consider "human capital" (skills and education) as the fourth factor of production, with entrepreneurship as a form of human capital. Yet others refer to intellectual capital. More recently, many have begun to see "social capital" as a factor, as contributing to production of goods and services.

Entrepreneurship

In markets, entrepreneurs combine the other factors of production, land, labor, and capital, to make a profit. Often these entrepreneurs are seen as innovators, developing new ways to produce and new products. In a planned economy, central planners decide how land, labor, and capital should be used to provide for maximum benefit for all citizens. Just as with market entrepreneurs, the benefits may mostly accrue to the entrepreneurs themselves.

The sociologist C. Wright Mills refers to "new entrepreneurs" who work within and between corporate and government bureaucracies in new and different ways.[12] Others (such as those practicing public choice theory) refer to "political entrepreneurs", i.e., politicians and other actors.

Much controversy rages about the benefits produced by entrepreneurship. But the real issue is about how well institutions they operate in (markets, planning, bureaucracies, government) serve the public. This concerns such issues as the relative importance of market failure and government failure.

In the book Accounting of Ideas, "intequity", a neologism, is abstracted from equity to add a newly researched production factor of the capitalist system. Equity, which is regarded as part of capital, was divided into equity and intequity. Entrepreneurship was divided into network-related matters and creating-related matters. Network-related matters function in the sphere of equity, and creating-related matters in spheres of intequities.[13]

Natural resources

Ayres and Warr (2010) are among the economists who criticize orthodox economics for overlooking the role of natural resources and the effects of declining resource capital.[9] See also: Natural resource economics

Energy

Exercise can be seen as individual factor of production, with an elastication larger than labor.[14]Acointegration analysis support results derived from linear exponential (LINEX) production functions.[15]

Cultural heritage

C. H. Douglas disagreed with classical economists who recognized only three factors of production. While Douglas did not deny the role of these factors in production, he considered the “Cultural heritage” as the primary factor. He defined cultural inheritance as the knowledge, techniques, and processes that have accrued to us incrementally from the origins of civilization (i.e., progress). Consequently, mankind does not have to keep "reinventing the wheel". "We are merely the administrators of that cultural inheritance, and to that extent, the cultural inheritance is the property of all of us, without exception.[16] Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and Karl Marx claimed that labor creates all value. While Douglas did not deny that all costs ultimately relate to labour charges of some sort (past or present), he denied that the present labour of the world creates all wealth. Douglas carefully distinguished between value, costs and prices. He claimed that one of the factors resulting in a misdirection of thought in terms of the nature and function of money was economists' near-obsession about values and their relation to prices and incomes.[17] While Douglas recognized "value in use" as a legitimate theory of values, he also considered values as subjective and not capable of being measured in an objective manner.

Peter Kropotkin argued for the common ownership of all intellectual and useful property due to the collective work that went into creating it. Kropotkin does not argue that the product of a worker's labor should belong to the worker. Instead, Kropotkin asserts that every individual product is essentially the work of everyone since every individual relies on the intellectual and physical labor of those who came before them as well as those who built the world around them. Because of this, Kropotkin proclaims that every human deserves an essential right to well-being because every human contributes to the collective social product:[18] Kropotkin goes on to say that the central obstacle preventing humanity from claiming this right is the state's violent protection of private property. Kropotkin compares this relationship to feudalism, saying that even if the forms have changed, the essential relationship between the propertied and the landless is the same as the relationship between a feudal lord and their serfs.[18]

See also

  • Cost of production theory of value
  • Diminishing returns
  • Economic inequality
  • Economics terminology that differs from common usage
  • Factor payments (economics)
  • Factor market
  • Factor world
  • Labor demand
  • Labor theory of value
  • Labour economics
  • Marginal factor cost
  • Means of production
  • Microeconomics
  • Pareto principle
  • Production relations
  • Production theory basics
  • Productivity model
  • Productivity world
  • Resource-Based View
  • Social metabolism
  • References

    1. ^ Paul A. Samuelson and William D. Nordhaus (2004). Economics, 18th ed., "Factors of production", "Capital", Human capital", and "Land" under Glossary of Terms.
  • ^ O'Sullivan, Arthur; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003). Economics: Principles in Action. Upper Saddle River, New Jersey 07458: Pearson Prentice Hall. p. 4. ISBN 978-0-13-063085-8.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location (link)
  • ^ Michael Parkin; Gerardo Esquivel (1999). Macroeconomía (in Spanish) (5th ed.). Mexico: Addison Wesley. p. 160. ISBN 968-444-441-9.
  • ^ Milton Friedman (2007). Price Theory. Transaction Publishers. p. 201. ISBN 978-0-202-30969-9.
  • ^ Classical price theory follows "costs of reproduction" and does not allow for "factor" gains. The great questions of Rent, Wages, and Profits must be explained by the proportions in which the whole produce is divided between landlords, capitalists, and laborers, and which are not essentially connected with the doctrine of value. (Ricardo Johnson, David, 1820; 1951, "The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo", edited by Piero Sraffa, 10 Volumes, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press 1951–1955, VIII, p. 197.
  • ^ Adam Smith (1776), The Wealth of Nations, B.I, Ch. 6, Of the Component Parts of the Price of Commodities in paragraph I.6.9.
  • ^ Benchimol, J., 2015, Money in the production function: a new Keynesian DSGE perspective, Southern Economic Journal, Volume 82, Issue 1, pp. 152-184.
  • ^ "Das Kapital", chapter 7, section 1.
  • ^ a b Robert U. Ayres; Benjamin Warr (2009). The Economic Growth Engine: How Energy and Work Drive Material Prosperity. Edward Elgar Publishing. ISBN 978-1-84844-182-8.
  • ^ a b Eric Zencey (2012). The Other Road to Serfdom & the Path to Sustainable Democracy. U of New England. ISBN 978-1-58465-961-7.
  • ^ Herman Daly; Joshua Farley (2011). Ecological Economics: Principles and Applications. Washington: Island. ISBN 978-1-59726-681-9.
  • ^ "White Collar: The American Middle Classes," 1956. Oxford: Galaxy Books, pp. 94–100.
  • ^ Pienaar, M.D. (2014). Intequisms: Accounting of ideas, chap. 6. Centurion: Africahead, 2nd edition, Kindle eBook, Amazon.com.
  • ^ R. Kümmel: The Productive Power of Energy and its Taxation, 4th European Congress Economy and Managers of Energy in Industry, Porto, Portugal, 27.-30. Nov. 2007.
  • ^ R. Stresing; D. Lindenberger; R. Kümmel (2008). "Cointegration of Output, Capital, Labor, and Energy" (PDF). European Physical Journal B. 66 (2): 279–287.
  • ^ Douglas, C.H. (22 January 1934). "The Monopolistic Idea" address at Melbourne Town Hall, Australia. The Australian League of Rights: Melbourne. Retrieved 28 February 2008.
  • ^ Douglas, C.H. (1973). Social Credit (PDF). New York: Gordon Press. p. 60. ISBN 0-9501126-1-5. Archived from the original (PDF) on 9 February 2010.
  • ^ a b Kropotkin, Petr Alekseevich (2015). The Conquest of Bread. Priestland, David (This edition, using the 1913 text, first published in Penguin Classics in 2015 ed.). London: Penguin Classics. ISBN 9780141396118. OCLC 913790063.
  • Further reading

    External links


    Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Factors_of_production&oldid=924534772"

    Categories: 
    Factors of production
    Production economics
    Labour economics
    Capital (economics)
    Resources
    Hidden categories: 
    CS1 maint: location
    CS1 Spanish-language sources (es)
    Articles lacking in-text citations from November 2017
    All articles lacking in-text citations
    CS1 German-language sources (de)
    Commons category link from Wikidata
     



    This page was last edited on 4 November 2019, at 13:01 (UTC).

    This version of the page has been revised. Besides normal editing, the reason for revision may have been that this version contains factual inaccuracies, vandalism, or material not compatible with the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License.



    Privacy policy

    About Wikipedia

    Disclaimers

    Contact Wikipedia

    Code of Conduct

    Developers

    Statistics

    Cookie statement

    Mobile view



    Wikimedia Foundation
    Powered by MediaWiki