Jump to content
 







Main menu
   


Navigation  



Main page
Contents
Current events
Random article
About Wikipedia
Contact us
Donate
 




Contribute  



Help
Learn to edit
Community portal
Recent changes
Upload file
 








Search  

































Create account

Log in
 









Create account
 Log in
 




Pages for logged out editors learn more  



Contributions
Talk
 



















Contents

   



(Top)
 


1 Biography  





2 The Economy of Happiness  





3 The Dynamic Universe  





4 Bibliography  





5 References  





6 External links  














James MacKaye






Dansk
Deutsch
Malagasy
مصرى
 

Edit links
 









Article
Talk
 

















Read
Edit
View history
 








Tools
   


Actions  



Read
Edit
View history
 




General  



What links here
Related changes
Upload file
Special pages
Permanent link
Page information
Cite this page
Get shortened URL
Download QR code
Wikidata item
 




Print/export  



Download as PDF
Printable version
 




In other projects  



Wikimedia Commons
 
















Appearance
   

 






From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
 


James MacKaye
Born

James Medbury MacKaye


(1872-04-08)April 8, 1872
New York, New York
DiedJanuary 22, 1935(1935-01-22) (aged 62)
Boston, Massachusetts
Education
  • Harvard University
  • Occupation(s)Engineer, philosopher
    Parents
  • Mary MacKaye (mother)
  • Relatives
  • Hazel MacKaye (sister)
  • Percy MacKaye (brother)
  • Signature

    James Medbury MacKaye (April 8, 1872 – January 22, 1935) was an American engineer and philosopher.

    Biography[edit]

    MacKaye was born in New York City, the son of actor Steele MacKaye and Mary (Medbery) MacKaye, and brother of poet Percy MacKaye, theater professional and suffragist Hazel MacKaye and conservationist Benton MacKaye.[1] He attended Grammar School No. 40 near Groton, Massachusetts[2] and Packard's Business College in New York, and in 1895 obtained an SB degree from Harvard University. In early 1890 MacKaye worked as a patent lawyer with the Census BureauinWashington, and in April 1891 he became secretary to Nathaniel Southgate Shaler at the Harvard Geological Department, holding for a number of years various minor appointments in that institution.[3] He joined the Boston firm Stone & Webster in 1899, where he worked as a research engineer. During the 28 years that he remained affiliated to that company he published several books on ethics, economics and politics, including Americanized Socialism, The Logic of Conduct and, most notably, The Economy of Happiness.

    The Economy of Happiness[edit]

    In this highly original but now largely forgotten work, MacKaye attempted to rescue the utilitarianismofJeremy Bentham from the changes that this doctrine had subsequently undergone as a result of John Stuart Mill's moderating influence. MacKaye conceived human beings—and sentient beings generally—as mechanisms of transforming resources into happiness, which he argued was the only intrinsic good. The goal of a society was therefore viewed by MacKaye as the problem of finding that arrangement which would produce the highest output of happiness attainable given the inputs available. As he wrote,

    That which society should seek to attain, the maximum surplus of happiness, may be referred to by different names according to the relation in which we think of it, e.g. the utilitarian end, the endorobject of utility, of society or of justice, and so forth. It is in the nature of a perfectly definite magnitude. Quantities of pain or pleasure may be regarded as magnitudes having the same definiteness as tons of pig iron, barrels of sugar, bushels of wheat, yards of cotton, or pounds of wool; and as political economy seeks to ascertain the conditions under which these commodities may be produced with the greatest efficiency--so the economy of happiness seeks to ascertain the conditions under which happiness, regarded as a commodity, may be produced with the greatest efficiency--how the maximum output of happiness may be achieved with the means available. In order to ascertain what these conditions are, we need to proceed as any manufacturer trained to his business would proceed, were he endeavoring to ascertain how he could most economically produce beer, or molasses, or oil, or tacks. He would satisfy himself by the inductive or common sense method what laws and resources of nature and of human nature were available under conditions as he found them, and the means thus available he would, to the best of his ability, adapt to his ends. Our problem is a similar one, and we shall adopt similar means to solve it.[4]

    MacKaye concluded that the form of social organization most conducive to that goal was a particular type of socialism which he dubbed "pantocracy".

    The Dynamic Universe[edit]

    In 1930 MacKaye startled the world after announcing an alternative to Albert Einstein's general theory of relativity. His theory of "radiation" was first presented at the twenty-ninth annual meeting of the American Philosophical Association held at Columbia University. Contrary to Einstein, MacKaye proposed a dynamic universe, assuming that all space was filled with radiation of super-frequency and super-penetration moving in all directions with the speed of light. As he claimed in the concluding paragraph of his paper, subsequently published in The Journal of Philosophy,[5] "If the radiation theory is sound, [...] it is plain that Einstein has discovered nothing about time, space, motion or acceleration unknown to the Newtonians, or shown that what they have hitherto assumed about those magnitudes is contrary to any fact in nature." The theory was described as "magnificent" by William Pepperell Montague and appears to have been generally well received by the audience. He later expanded his views in the book, The Dynamic Universe, published in 1931.[6]

    MacKaye entered the academic profession only in 1931, when he became a lecturer at Rollins College. The following year he was appointed Professor of Philosophy at Dartmouth College.[7] At the end of 1934 MacKaye was hospitalized at the Massachusetts General HospitalinBoston, where he had a gall bladder surgery. Although the doctors predicted recovery, he died a week later.[8] A service was held on January 24 at the Memorial Church of Harvard University, where his remains were cremated.[6]

    Bibliography[edit]

    References[edit]

    1. ^ Walter Lippmann, "All the MacKayes", The Internationalist, vol. 3, no. 2 (January, 1911), p. 29.
  • ^ Larry Anderson, Benton MacKaye: Conservationist, Planner, and Creator of the Appalachian Trail, Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 2002, p. 16.
  • ^ The Papers of The Mackaye Family in the Dartmouth College Library.
  • ^ The Economy of Happiness, pp. 183-184.
  • ^ 'The Theory of Relativity: For What Is It a Disguise?', Vol. 27, No. 5 (February 27, 1930), pp. 126-134.
  • ^ a b "Prof. J. M. M'Kaye Scientist, Dies, 62," The New York Times, January 23, 1935, books art-books sect., p. 17.
  • ^ W. K. Wright, Memorial Notice, The Philosophical Review, Vol. 45, No. 2 (March, 1936), p. 176.
  • ^ Anderson, Benton MacKaye, p. 259.
  • External links[edit]


    Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=James_MacKaye&oldid=1155966891"

    Categories: 
    1872 births
    1935 deaths
    American non-fiction writers
    Harvard University alumni
    Relativity critics
    Hidden categories: 
    Articles with short description
    Short description is different from Wikidata
    Use mdy dates from December 2020
    Biography with signature
    Articles with hCards
    Commons category link from Wikidata
    Articles with FAST identifiers
    Articles with ISNI identifiers
    Articles with VIAF identifiers
    Articles with WorldCat Entities identifiers
    Articles with J9U identifiers
    Articles with LCCN identifiers
    Articles with NTA identifiers
    Articles with SNAC-ID identifiers
    Articles with SUDOC identifiers
     



    This page was last edited on 20 May 2023, at 15:31 (UTC).

    Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License 4.0; additional terms may apply. By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., a non-profit organization.



    Privacy policy

    About Wikipedia

    Disclaimers

    Contact Wikipedia

    Code of Conduct

    Developers

    Statistics

    Cookie statement

    Mobile view



    Wikimedia Foundation
    Powered by MediaWiki