Jump to content
 







Main menu
   


Navigation  



Main page
Contents
Current events
Random article
About Wikipedia
Contact us
Donate
 




Contribute  



Help
Learn to edit
Community portal
Recent changes
Upload file
 








Search  

































Create account

Log in
 









Create account
 Log in
 




Pages for logged out editors learn more  



Contributions
Talk
 



















Contents

   



(Top)
 


1 Biography  





2 Contributions to economics  



2.1  "The Nature of the Firm"  





2.2  "The Problem of Social Cost"  





2.3  Law and economics  





2.4  Coase theorem  





2.5  Coase conjecture  







3 Political views  





4 Ronald Coase Institute  





5 Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics  





6 Publications  





7 See also  





8 References  



8.1  Bibliography  







9 External links  














Ronald Coase






العربية
Aragonés
Azərbaycanca

Беларуская
Български
Català
Čeština
Dansk
Deutsch
Eesti
Español
Esperanto
Euskara
فارسی
Français
Gàidhlig

Հայերեն
Ido
Bahasa Indonesia
Íslenska
Italiano
עברית
Кыргызча
Latina
Latviešu
Lëtzebuergesch
Lietuvių
Magyar
مصرى
Bahasa Melayu
Nederlands

Norsk bokmål
Oʻzbekcha / ўзбекча
پنجابی
Plattdüütsch
Polski
Português
Română
Русский
Simple English
Slovenčina
Suomi
Svenska
ி

Türkçe
Українська
اردو
Tiếng Vit

Yorùbá

 

Edit links
 









Article
Talk
 

















Read
Edit
View history
 








Tools
   


Actions  



Read
Edit
View history
 




General  



What links here
Related changes
Upload file
Special pages
Permanent link
Page information
Cite this page
Get shortened URL
Download QR code
Wikidata item
 




Print/export  



Download as PDF
Printable version
 




In other projects  



Wikimedia Commons
Wikiquote
 
















Appearance
   

 






From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
 


Ronald Coase

Born

Ronald Harry Coase


(1910-12-29)29 December 1910
Willesden, London, England

Died

2 September 2013(2013-09-02) (aged 102)
Chicago, Illinois, U.S.

Resting place

Graceland Cemetery, Chicago

Education

London School of Economics (BCom)
University of Chicago
University of London (DSc)

Spouse

Marian Ruth Hartung

(m. 1937⁠–⁠2012)​ 9 children

Academic career

Institution

University of Dundee
London School of Economics
University of Chicago
University of Virginia
University at Buffalo

Field

Law and economics

School or
tradition

New institutional economics
Chicago School of Economics

Contributions

Coase theorem
Analysis of transaction costs
Coase conjecture

Awards

Nobel Prize in Economics (1991)

InformationatIDEAS / RePEc

Ronald Harry Coase (/ˈks/; 29 December 1910 – 2 September 2013) was a British economist and author. Coase was educated at the London School of Economics, where he was a member of the faculty until 1951. He was the Clifton R. Musser Professor of Economics at the University of Chicago Law School, where he arrived in 1964 and remained for the rest of his life. He received the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1991.[1]

Part of a serieson

Capitalism

  • Business
  • Business cycle
  • Businessperson
  • Capital
  • Capital accumulation
  • Capital markets
  • Company
  • Corporation
  • Competitive markets
  • Economic interventionism
  • Economic liberalism
  • Economic surplus
  • Entrepreneurship
  • Fictitious capital
  • Financial market
  • Free price system
  • Free market
  • Goods and services
  • Investor
  • Invisible hand
  • Visible hand
  • Liberalization
  • Marginalism
  • Money
  • Private property
  • Privatization
  • Profit
  • Rent seeking
  • Supply and demand
  • Surplus value
  • Value
  • Wage labour
  • Authoritarian
  • Corporate
  • Dirigist
  • Free-market
  • Humanistic
  • Laissez-faire
  • Liberal
  • Libertarian
  • Market
  • Mercantilist
  • Mixed
  • Monopoly
  • National
  • Neoliberal
  • Nordic
  • Private
  • Raw
  • Regulated market
  • Regulatory
  • Rhine
  • Social
  • State
  • State-sponsored
  • Welfare
  • Austrian
  • Chartalism
  • Chicago
  • Classical
  • Institutional
  • Keynesian
  • Market monetarism
  • Critique of political economy
  • Critique of work
  • Marxist
  • Monetarist
  • Neoclassical
  • New institutional
  • Supply-side
  • Capitalism and Islam
  • Commercial Revolution
  • Feudalism
  • Industrial Revolution
  • Mercantilism
  • Primitive accumulation
  • Physiocracy
  • Simple commodity production
  • Consumer
  • Community
  • Corporate
  • Crony
  • Finance
  • Global
  • Illiberal
  • Late
  • Marxist
  • Merchant
  • Progressive
  • Rentier
  • State monopoly
  • Technological
  • Mill
  • Ricardo
  • Malthus
  • Say
  • Marx
  • Friedman
  • Hayek
  • Keynes
  • Marshall
  • Pareto
  • Walras
  • von Mises
  • Rand
  • Rothbard
  • Schumpeter
  • Veblen
  • Weaver
  • Weber
  • Coase
  • Capitalist propaganda
  • Capitalist realism
  • Capitalist state
  • Consumerism
  • Crisis theory
  • Criticism of capitalism
  • Critique of political economy
  • Critique of work
  • Cronyism
  • Culture of capitalism
  • Evergreening
  • Exploitation of labour
  • Globalization
  • History
  • History of theory
  • Market economy
  • Periodizations of capitalism
  • Perspectives on capitalism
  • Post-capitalism
  • Speculation
  • Spontaneous order
  • Venture philanthropy
  • Wage slavery
  • Authoritarian
  • Classical liberalism
  • Democratic
  • Dirigisme
  • Eco
  • Humanistic
  • Inclusive
  • Liberal
  • Liberalism
  • Libertarian
  • Neo
  • Neoliberalism
  • Objectivism
  • Ordoliberalism
  • Privatism
  • Right-libertarianism
  • Third Way
  • icon Business portal
  • t
  • e
  • Part of a series on the

    Chicago school
    of economics

  • Neoliberalism
  • Positive non-interventionism
  • George Mason University
  • Library of Economics and Liberty
  • Reason Foundation
  • Monetarism
  • Neoclassical economics
  • Fogel
  • Sowell
  • David Friedman
  • Milton Friedman
  • Knight
  • Lucas Jr.
  • Schultz
  • Stigler
  • Economic growth
  • Economic rationalism
  • Efficient market
  • Friedman rule
  • k-percent rule
  • Game theory
  • GDP
  • Homo economicus
  • International economics, finance, trade
  • Laffer curve
  • Monetary economics
  • Public choice
  • Quantity of money
  • Rational agent, choice, expectations
  • Symmetrical inflation target
  • Deregulation
  • Economic freedom
  • Economic integration, interdependence
  • Economic liberalization
  • Exchange rate
  • Fiat money
  • Foreign exchange reserves
  • Free markets
  • Free trade
  • Globalization
  • Inflation adjustment
  • Inflation targeting
  • Intellectual property
  • Laissez-faire
  • Marketization
  • Negative income tax
  • Open market operations
  • Private property
  • Privatization
  • School vouchers
  • Single market
  • Tax cuts
  • Tax reform
  • Anti-globalization
  • Perspectives on capitalism
  • icon Capitalism portal
  • diagram Libertarianism portal
  • icon Politics portal
  • t
  • e
  • Coase believed economists should study real-world wealth creation, in the manner of Adam Smith, stating, "It is suicidal for the field to slide into a hard science of choice, ignoring the influences of society, history, culture, and politics on the working of the economy."[2] He believed economic study should reduce emphasis on Price Theory or theoretical markets and instead focus on real markets.[3][4] He established the case for the corporation as a means to pay the costs of operating a marketplace.[3] Coase is best known for two articles: "The Nature of the Firm" (1937), which introduces the concept of transaction costs to explain the nature and limits of firms; and "The Problem of Social Cost" (1960), which suggests that well-defined property rights could overcome the problems of externalities if it were not for transaction costs (see Coase theorem). Additionally, Coase's transaction costs approach has been influential in modern organizational economics, where it was re-introduced by Oliver E. Williamson.

    Biography[edit]

    Ronald Coase

    Ronald Harry Coase was born in Willesden, a suburb of London, on 29 December 1910. His father, Henry Joseph Coase (1884–1973) was a telegraphist for the post office, as was his mother, Rosalie Elizabeth Coase (née Giles; 1882–1972), before marriage.[5][6][7] As a child, Coase had a weakness in his legs, for which he was required to wear leg-irons. Due to this problem, he attended the school for physical defectives. At the age of 12, he was able to enter Kilburn Grammar School on scholarship. At Kilburn, he studied for the intermediate examination of the University of London as an external student in 1927–29.[8][9]

    Coase then continued his studies at the University of London, enrolling as an internal student of the London School of Economics, where he took courses with Arnold Plant[8] and received a Bachelor of Commerce degree in 1932. During his undergraduate studies, Coase received the Sir Ernest Cassel Travelling Scholarship which he used to visit the University of Chicago in 1931–1932 studying with Frank Knight and Jacob Viner. Coase's colleagues would later admit that they did not remember this first visit.[10] Between 1932 and 1934, Coase was an assistant lecturer at the Dundee School of Economics and Commerce, which later became part of the University of Dundee. Subsequently, Coase was an assistant lecturer in commerce at the University of Liverpool between 1934 and 1935 before returning to London School of Economics as a member of staff until 1951 in which year he was awarded an earned doctorate in economics from the University of London. He then started to work at the University at Buffalo and retained his British citizenship after moving to the United States in the 1950s.[11] In 1958, he moved to the University of Virginia. Coase settled at the University of Chicago in 1964 and became the co-editor of the Journal of Law and Economics with Aaron Director.[12] He was also for a time a trustee of the Philadelphia Society.[13] He received the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1991.

    Coase's grave at Graceland Cemetery

    Nearing his 100th birthday, Coase was working on a book concerning the rise of the economies of China and Vietnam.[14] In an interview, Coase explained the mission of the Coase China Society and his vision of economics and the part to be played by Chinese economists.[15][16] This became "How China Became Capitalist" (2012) co-authored with Ning Wang. Coase was honoured and received an honorary doctorate from the university at Buffalo Department of Economics in May 2012.[17]

    Coase married Marian Ruth Hartung of Chicago, Illinois in Willesden, England, 7 August 1937.[6] Although they were unable to have children, they were married 75 years until her death on 17 October 2012, making him one of the longest-married Nobel Prize laureates.[4][18] Coase himself died in Chicago on 2 September 2013, at the age of 102.[19] Both are buried at Graceland Cemetery in Chicago.

    He was praised across the political spectrum, with Slate calling him "one of the most distinguished economists in the world"[20] and Forbes calling him "the greatest of the many great University of Chicago economists".[21] The Washington Post called his work over eight decades "impossible to summarize" while recommending five of his papers to read.[22]

    Contributions to economics[edit]

    "The Nature of the Firm"[edit]

    In "The Nature of the Firm" (1937), a brief but highly influential essay, Coase attempts to explain why the economy features a number of business firms instead of consisting exclusively of a multitude of independent, self-employed people who contract with one another. Given that "production could be carried on without any organization [that is, firms] at all", Coase asks, why and under what conditions should we expect firms to emerge?

    Since modern firms can only emerge when an entrepreneur of some sort begins to hire people, Coase's analysis proceeds by considering the conditions under which it makes sense for an entrepreneur to seek hired help instead of contracting out for some particular task.

    The traditional economic theory of the time (in the tradition of Adam Smith) suggested that, because the market is "efficient" (that is, those who are best at providing each good or service most cheaply are already doing so), it should always be cheaper to contract out than to hire.

    Coase noted, however, a number of transaction costs involved in using the market; the cost of obtaining a good or service via the market actually exceeds the price of the good. Other costs, including search and information costs, bargaining costs, keeping trade secrets, and policing and enforcement costs, can all potentially add to the cost of procuring something from another party. This suggests that firms will arise which can internalise the production of goods and services required to deliver a product, thus avoiding these costs. This argument sets the stage for the later contributions by Oliver Williamson: markets and hierarchies are alternative co-ordination mechanisms for economic transactions. [23][24]

    There is a natural limit to what a firm can produce internally, however. Coase notices "decreasing returns to the entrepreneur function", including increasing overhead costs and increasing propensity for an overwhelmed manager to make mistakes in resource allocation. These factors become countervailing costs to the use of the firm.

    Coase argues that the size of a firm (as measured by how many contractual relations are "internal" to the firm and how many "external") is a result of finding an optimal balance between the competing tendencies of the costs outlined above. In general, making the firm larger will initially be advantageous, but the decreasing returns indicated above will eventually kick in, preventing the firm from growing indefinitely.

    Other things being equal, therefore, a firm will tend to be larger:

    The first two costs will increase with the spatial distribution of the transactions organised and the dissimilarity of the transactions. This explains why firms tend to either be in different geographic locations or to perform different functions. Additionally, technology changes that mitigate the cost of organising transactions across space may allow firms to become larger – the advent of the telephone and of cheap air travel, for example, would be expected to increase the size of firms.

    A further exploration of the dichotomy between markets and hierarchies as co-ordination mechanisms for economic transactions derived a third alternative way called Commons based peer production, in which individuals successfully collaborate on large-scale projects following a diverse cluster of motivational drives and social signals.

    "The Problem of Social Cost"[edit]

    Coase at the University of Chicago Law School in 2003

    Upon publishing his article The Federal Communications Commission in 1959, Coase received negative feedback from the faculty at the University of Chicago over his conclusions and apparent conflicts with A. C. Pigou. According to Coase, "What I said was thought to run counter to Pigou's analysis by a number of economists at the University of Chicago and was therefore, according to them, wrong. At a meeting in Chicago I was able to convince these economists that I was right and Pigou's analysis faulty." Coase had presented his paper in 1960 during a seminar in Chicago, to twenty senior economist including George Stigler and Milton Friedman. He gradually won over the usually skeptic audience, in what has later been considered a "paradigm-shifting moment" in the genesis of Chicago Law and Economics.[25] Coase would join the Chicago faculty four years later.

    Published in the Journal of Law and Economics in 1960, while Coase was a member of the Economics department at the University of Virginia, "The Problem of Social Cost" provided the key insight that it is unclear where the blame for externalities lies. The example he gave was of a rancher whose cattle stray onto the cropland of his neighbour. If the rancher is made to restrict his cattle, he is harmed just as the farmer is if the cattle remain unrestrained.

    Coase argued that without transaction costs the initial assignment of property rights makes no difference to whether or not the farmer and rancher can achieve the economically efficient outcome. If the cost of restraining cattle by, say, building a fence, is less than the cost of crop damage, the fence will be built. The initial assignment of property rights determines who builds the fence. If the farmer is responsible for the crop damage, the farmer will pay for the fence (as long the fence costs less than the crop damage). The allocation of property rights is primarily an equity issue, with consequences for the distribution of income and wealth, rather than an efficiency issue.

    With sufficient transaction costs, initial property rights matter for both equity and efficiency. From the point of view of economic efficiency, property rights should be assigned such that the owner of the rights wants to take the economically efficient action. To elaborate, if it is efficient not to restrict the cattle, the rancher should be given the rights (so that cattle can move about freely), whereas if it is efficient to restrict the cattle, the farmer should be given the rights over the movement of the cattle (so the cattle are restricted).

    This seminal argument forms the basis of the famous Coase theorem as labelled by Stigler. In 1990, Coase wrote that he feared "The Problem of Social Cost" had been widely misunderstood. [26]

    Law and economics[edit]

    Coase at the University of Chicago Law School

    Though trained as an economist, Coase spent much of his career working in a law school. He is a central figure in the development of the subfield of law and economics. He viewed law and economics as having two parts, the first "using the economists' approach and concepts to analyze the working of the legal system, often called the economic analysis of the law"; and the second "a study of the influence of the legal system on the working of the economic system."[27] Coase said that the second part "is the part of law and economics in which I am most interested."

    In his Simons Lecture celebrating the centennial of the University of Chicago, titled "Law and Economics at Chicago", Coase noted that he only accidentally wandered into the field:

    It is generally agreed that this article has had an immense influence on legal scholarship, but this was no part of my intention. For me, "The Problem of Social Cost" was an essay in economics. It was aimed at economists. What I wanted to do was to improve our analysis of the working of the economic system. Law came into article because, in a regime of positive transaction costs, the character of the law becomes one of the main factors determining the performance of the economy. If transaction costs were zero (as is assumed in standard economic theory) we can imagine people contracting around the law whenever the value of production would be increased by a change in the legal position. But in a regime of positive transaction costs, such contracting would not occur whenever transaction costs were greater than the gain that such a redistribution of rights would bring. As a consequence the rights which individuals possess will commonly be those established by the law, which in these circumstances can be said to control the economy. As I have said, in "The Problem of Social Cost" I had no intention of making a contribution to legal scholarship. I referred to legal cases because they afforded examples of real situations as against the imaginary ones normally used by economists in their analysis. It was undoubtedly an economist who invented the widget. But in "The Problem of Social Cost" I did something else. I pointed out that the judges in their opinions often seemed to show a better understanding of the economic problem than did many economists even though their views were not always expressed in a very explicit fashion. I did this not to praise the judges but to shame economists.[28]

    Despite wandering accidentally into law and economics, the opportunity to edit the Journal of Law and Economics was instrumental in bringing him to the University of Chicago:

    [W]hen I was approached to fill Aaron Director's place on his retirement, what I found most attractive about coming to Chicago was the opportunity it gave me of editing the Journal. Indeed, it is probable that without the Journal I would not have come to Chicago. I knew nothing of the original aim of the Journal. What I wanted to do was to encourage the type of research which I had advocated in "The Problem of Social Cost," and I used my editorship of the Journal as a means of bringing this about.[28]

    Coase believed that the University of Chicago was the intellectual center of law and economics. He concluded his Simons lecture by stating:

    I am very much aware that, in concentrating in this lecture on law and economics at Chicago, I have neglected other significant contributions to the subject made elsewhere such as those by Guido Calabresi at Yale, by Donald Turner at Harvard, and by others. But it can hardly be denied that in the emergence of the subject of law and economics, Chicago has played a very significant part and one of which the University can be proud.[28]

    Coase theorem[edit]

    Inlaw and economics, the Coase theorem (/ˈks/) describes the economic efficiency of an economic allocation or outcome in the presence of externalities. The theorem states that if trade in an externality is possible and there are sufficiently low transaction costs, bargaining will lead to a Pareto efficient outcome regardless of the initial allocation of property. In practice, obstacles to bargaining or poorly defined property rights can prevent Coasean bargaining. This 'theorem' is commonly attributed to Coase.

    Coase conjecture[edit]

    Another important contribution of Coase is the Coase conjecture, which is an informal argument that durable goods monopolists do not have market power because they are unable to commit to not lowering their prices in future periods.

    Political views[edit]

    When asked what he considered his politics to be, Coase stated,

    I really don't know. I don't reject any policy without considering what its results are. If someone says there's going to be regulation, I don't say that regulation will be bad. Let's see. What we discover is that most regulation does produce, or has produced in recent times, a worse result. But I wouldn't like to say that all regulation would have this effect because one can think of circumstances in which it doesn't.[29]

    Coase admitted that early in life, he aligned himself with socialism.

    As a young man I was a Socialist. The first challenge to this belief came when, in 1931, 5 months before I took the final examinations for the B.Com. degree, I attended Arnold Plant's seminar at the London School of Economics (LSE). He introduced me to Adam Smith's invisible hand and to the advantages of a competitive system. He also pointed out that government schemes in the economic sphere were often ill-conceived and were introduced to placate special interests. I adopted many of Plant's positions but continued to regard myself as a Socialist. That this meant holding what could be considered, and were, inconsistent positions was not unusual at that time. Abba Lerner, a fellow student and a fine theorist, with whom I had a very friendly relation, also believed in the virtues of a competitive system but was even more attached to Socialism than I was.[27]

    Guido Calabresi wrote that Coase's focus on transaction costs in The Nature of the Firm was the result of his socialist beliefs. Reflecting on this, Coase wrote: "It is very difficult to know where one's ideas come from but for all I know he may well be right." Coase continued:

    My socialist sympathies gradually fell away and this process was accentuated as a result of being assigned in 1935 at LSE the course on the Economics of Public Utilities. I soon found out that very little was known about British public utilities and I set about making a series of historical studies on the water, gas, and electricity supply industries and of the Post Office and broadcasting. These researches taught me much about the public utility industries and they certainly made me aware of the defects of government operation of these industries, whether municipal or through nationalisation. These researches were interrupted by the war, when I joined the civil service, at first, for a short period, in the Forestry Commission, then responsible for timber production, and for the rest of the war, in the Central Statistical Office, one of the offices of the War Cabinet. This war-time experience did not significantly influence my views but I could not help noticing that, with the country in mortal danger and despite the leadership of Winston Churchill, government departments often seemed more concerned to defend their own interests than those of the country.[27]

    Ronald Coase Institute[edit]

    Coase was research advisor to the Ronald Coase Institute, an organisation that promotes research on institutions and organizations – the laws, rules, customs, and norms – that govern real economic systems, with particular support for young scholars from developing and transitional countries.

    Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics[edit]

    Coase at a conference in 2008 with Richard Sandor

    The University of Chicago Law School carries on the legacy of Ronald Coase through the mission of the Coase-Sandor Institute for Law and Economics. Each year, the University of Chicago Law School hosts the Coase Lecture, which was delivered in 2003 by Ronald Coase himself.[30]

    Publications[edit]

    See also[edit]

    References[edit]

  • ^ Coase, Ronald (1 December 2012). "Saving Economics from the Economists". Harvard Business Review. ISSN 0017-8012. Retrieved 21 January 2022.
  • ^ a b Henderson, David R. (3 September 2013). "The Man Who Resisted 'Blackboard Economics'". The Wall Street Journal. ISSN 0099-9660. Retrieved 25 December 2019.
  • ^ a b Littlewood, Mark (4 September 2013). "Ronald Coase obituary". The Guardian. Retrieved 9 September 2018.
  • ^ "Coase, Ronald Harry". Who's Who in America 2000, Millennium Edition. Vol. I (A-K) (54th ed.). New Providence, NJ: Marquis Who's Who. 1999. p. 891. ISBN 0-8379-0200-2. Retrieved 16 July 2023 – via Internet Archive.
  • ^ a b "COASE, Ronald Harry". The International Who's Who (70th ed.). London & New York: Routledge. 2006. p. 406. ISBN 1-85743-366-1. Retrieved 16 July 2023.
  • ^ "COASE, Prof. Ronald Harry". Who's Who 2007: An Annual Biographical Dictionary (159 ed.). London: A & C Black. 2007. p. 447. ISBN 978-0-7136-7526-9. Retrieved 16 July 2023 – via Internet Archive.
  • ^ a b "Ronald Coase. "Nobel Prize Autobiography," 1991".
  • ^ Breit, William and Barry T. Hirsch. Lives of the Laureates, 4th ed. Cambridge, Mass: The MIT Press, 2004.
  • ^ Kitch, Edmund W. (1983). "The Fire of Truth: A Remembrance of Law and Economics at Chicago, 1932–1970". Journal of Law and Economics. 26 (1): 163–234. doi:10.1086/467030. JSTOR 725189. S2CID 153525815.
  • ^ "U. of Chicago Professor Wins Nobel Economics Prize". Archived from the original on 28 February 2020. Retrieved 17 March 2011.
  • ^ "Aaron Director, Founder of the field of Law and Economics". www-news.uchicago.edu. Retrieved 7 September 2019.
  • ^ "Trustees". Phillysoc.org. Archived from the original on 27 August 2013. Retrieved 3 September 2013.
  • ^ "99-year-old economist researches the rise of China and Vietnam". VietNamNet Bridge. 24 March 2010. Archived from the original on 3 September 2010.
  • ^ "Coase China Society Interviews Ronald Coase". Chicago University Law School. 3 January 2011.
  • ^ "Interview with Professor Ronald Coase". Unirule Institute of Economics. 3 January 2011. Archived from the original on 17 January 2011.
  • ^ http://economics.buffalo.edu/ Robert Coase Honorary Doctorate
  • ^ Lyons, Patrick J. (3 September 2013). "Ronald H. Coase, a Law Professor And Leading Economist, Dies at 102". The New York Times.
  • ^ Galer, Sarah. "Ronald H. Coase, Founding Scholar in Law and Economics, 1910–2013". Law.uchicago.edu. University of Chicago Law School. Archived from the original on 5 September 2013. Retrieved 3 September 2013.
  • ^ Yglesias, Matthew (3 September 2013). "Ronald Coase, the Economist Who Explained Why We Have Companies". Slate.
  • ^ Smith, Fred (3 September 2013). "Ronald Coase Was The Greatest of the Many Great University of Chicago Economists". Forbes.
  • ^ Matthews, Dylan (3 September 2013). "Ronald Coase is dead. Here are five of his papers you need to read". The Washington Post.
  • ^ Hein Schreuder, "Coase, Hayek and Hierarchy", In: S. Lindenberg & Hein Schreuder, editors, Interdisciplinary Perspectives on Organization Studies, Pergamon Press
  • ^ Knight, Jack (1992). Institutions and Social Conflict. Cambridge University Press. p. 12. ISBN 978-0-521-42189-8.
  • ^ Davies, William (2014). The Limits of Neoliberalism: Authority, Sovereignty and the Logic of Competition. Sage. pp. 87–90. ISBN 978-1473905337.
  • ^ The Problem of Social Cost University of Chicago Law School
  • ^ a b c Coase, R. H. (1996). "Law and Economics and A.W. Brian Simpson". Journal of Legal Studies. 25 (1): 103–119. doi:10.1086/467973. JSTOR 724523. S2CID 146511123.
  • ^ a b c Coase, R. H. (1993). "Law and Economics at Chicago". Journal of Law and Economics. 36 (1): 239–254. doi:10.1086/467274. JSTOR 725475. S2CID 153402423.
  • ^ "Looking for results". Reason magazine. January 1997.
  • ^ Coase, 2003 Coase Lecture: Ronald; Present, "The; Law, Future of; Economics" (6 July 2009). "2003 Coase Lecture: Ronald Coase, "The Present and Future of Law and Economics" | University of Chicago Law School". www.law.uchicago.edu. Retrieved 22 December 2023.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)
  • Bibliography[edit]

    https://www.researchgate.net/publication/374337555_Ronald_Coase_in_the_French_Wikipedia

    External links[edit]

    Awards

    Preceded by

    Harry M. Markowitz
    Merton H. Miller
    William F. Sharpe

    Laureate of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics
    1991

    Succeeded by

    Gary S. Becker

    Institutional economists

  • Clarence Edwin Ayres
  • Joe S. Bain
  • Shimshon Bichler
  • Robert A. Brady
  • Daniel Bromley
  • Ha-Joon Chang
  • John Maurice Clark
  • John R. Commons
  • Richard T. Ely
  • Robert H. Frank
  • John Kenneth Galbraith
  • Walton Hale Hamilton
  • Orris C. Herfindahl
  • Albert O. Hirschman
  • Geoffrey Hodgson
  • János Kornai
  • Simon Kuznets
  • Hunter Lewis
  • Jesse W. Markham
  • Wesley Clair Mitchell
  • Gunnar Myrdal
  • Jonathan Nitzan
  • Warren Samuels
  • François Simiand
  • Herbert A. Simon
  • Frank Stilwell
  • George W. Stocking Sr.
  • Lars Pålsson Syll
  • Thorstein Veblen
  • Edward Lawrence Wheelwright
  • Erich Zimmermann
  • New institutional economists

  • Armen Alchian
  • Masahiko Aoki
  • Steven N. S. Cheung
  • Ronald Coase
  • Harold Demsetz
  • Avner Greif
  • Claude Ménard
  • Douglass North
  • Mancur Olson
  • Elinor Ostrom
  • Oliver E. Williamson
  • Behavioral economists

  • Dan Ariely
  • Nava Ashraf
  • Ofer Azar
  • Douglas Bernheim
  • Samuel Bowles
  • Sarah Brosnan
  • Colin Camerer
  • David Cesarini
  • Kay-Yut Chen
  • Rachel Croson
  • Werner De Bondt
  • Paul Dolan
  • Stephen Duneier
  • Catherine C. Eckel
  • Armin Falk
  • Urs Fischbacher
  • Herbert Gintis
  • Uri Gneezy
  • David Halpern
  • Charles A. Holt
  • David Ryan Just
  • Daniel Kahneman
  • Ariel Kalil
  • George Katona
  • Jeffrey R. Kling
  • George Loewenstein
  • Graham Loomes
  • Brigitte C. Madrian
  • Gary McClelland
  • Matteo Motterlini
  • Sendhil Mullainathan
  • Michael Norton
  • Matthew Rabin
  • Howard Rachlin
  • Klaus M. Schmidt
  • Eldar Shafir
  • Hersh Shefrin
  • Robert J. Shiller
  • Uwe Sunde
  • Richard Thaler
  • Amos Tversky
  • Robert W. Vishny
  • Georg Weizsäcker
  • Economic sociologists

  • Fred L. Block
  • James S. Coleman
  • Paul DiMaggio
  • Paula England
  • Mark Granovetter
  • Donald Angus MacKenzie
  • Joel M. Podolny
  • Lynette Spillman
  • Richard Swedberg
  • Laurent Thévenot
  • Carlo Trigilia
  • Harrison White
  • Viviana Zelizer
  • Key concepts and ideas

  • Administered prices
  • Barriers to entry
  • Bounded rationality
  • Conspicuous consumption
  • Conspicuous leisure
  • Conventional wisdom
  • Countervailing power
  • Effective competition
  • Herfindahl index
  • Hiding hand principle
  • Hirschman cycle
  • Instrumentalism
  • Kuznets cycles
  • Market concentration
  • Market power
  • Market structure
  • Penalty of taking the lead
  • Satisficing
  • Shortage economy
  • Structure–conduct–performance paradigm
  • Technostructure
  • Theory of two-level planning
  • Veblen goods
  • Veblenian dichotomy
  • Related fields

  • Development economics
  • English historical school of economics
  • Evolutionary economics
  • Evolutionary psychology
  • French historical school
  • Historical school of economics
  • Legal realism
  • Microeconomics
  • Post-Keynesian economics
  • Founders

  • Henry Calvert Simons
  • Jacob Viner
  • Theodore Schultz
  • George Stigler
  • Monetarism

  • Anna Schwartz
  • Karl Brunner
  • Phillip D. Cagan
  • Harry G. Johnson
  • Allan H. Meltzer
  • David Laidler
  • Scott Sumner
  • New economic history

  • Robert Fogel
  • Robert M. Townsend
  • New social economics

  • Gary Becker
  • James Heckman
  • Thomas Sowell
  • Sherwin Rosen
  • Kevin M. Murphy
  • John A. List
  • Sudhir Venkatesh
  • Steven Levitt
  • Roland Fryer
  • Public choice school

  • Gordon Tullock
  • Randall Holcombe
  • Anthony Downs
  • William A. Niskanen
  • Bryan Caplan
  • Law and economics

  • Aaron Director
  • William Landes
  • Richard Posner
  • Richard Epstein
  • Robert Bork
  • Frank H. Easterbrook
  • Business and finance

  • Myron Scholes
  • Merton Miller
  • Julian Lincoln Simon
  • Eugene Fama
  • Kenneth French
  • Campbell Harvey
  • Lars Peter Hansen
  • 1969–1975

  • 1970: Paul A. Samuelson
  • 1971: Simon Kuznets
  • 1972: John R. Hicks / Kenneth J. Arrow
  • 1973: Wassily Leontief
  • 1974: Gunnar Myrdal / Friedrich August von Hayek
  • 1975: Leonid Vitaliyevich Kantorovich / Tjalling C. Koopmans
  • 1976–2000

  • 1977: Bertil Ohlin / James E. Meade
  • 1978: Herbert A. Simon
  • 1979: Theodore W. Schultz / Sir Arthur Lewis
  • 1980: Lawrence R. Klein
  • 1981: James Tobin
  • 1982: George J. Stigler
  • 1983: Gérard Debreu
  • 1984: Richard Stone
  • 1985: Franco Modigliani
  • 1986: James M. Buchanan Jr.
  • 1987: Robert M. Solow
  • 1988: Maurice Allais
  • 1989: Trygve Haavelmo
  • 1990: Harry M. Markowitz / Merton H. Miller / William F. Sharpe
  • 1991: Ronald H. Coase
  • 1992: Gary S. Becker
  • 1993: Robert W. Fogel / Douglass C. North
  • 1994: John C. Harsanyi / John F. Nash Jr. / Reinhard Selten
  • 1995: Robert E. Lucas Jr.
  • 1996: James A. Mirrlees / William Vickrey
  • 1997: Robert C. Merton / Myron S. Scholes
  • 1998: Amartya Sen
  • 1999: Robert A. Mundell
  • 2000: James J. Heckman / Daniel L. McFadden
  • 2001–present

  • 2002: Daniel Kahneman / Vernon L. Smith
  • 2003: Robert F. Engle III / Clive W.J. Granger
  • 2004: Finn E. Kydland / Edward C. Prescott
  • 2005: Robert J. Aumann / Thomas C. Schelling
  • 2006: Edmund S. Phelps
  • 2007: Leonid Hurwicz / Eric S. Maskin / Roger B. Myerson
  • 2008: Paul Krugman
  • 2009: Elinor Ostrom / Oliver E. Williamson
  • 2010: Peter A. Diamond / Dale T. Mortensen / Christopher A. Pissarides
  • 2011: Thomas J. Sargent / Christopher A. Sims
  • 2012: Alvin E. Roth / Lloyd S. Shapley
  • 2013: Eugene F. Fama / Lars Peter Hansen / Robert J. Shiller
  • 2014: Jean Tirole
  • 2015: Angus Deaton
  • 2016: Oliver Hart / Bengt Holmström
  • 2017: Richard H. Thaler
  • 2018: William Nordhaus / Paul Romer
  • 2019: Abhijit Banerjee / Esther Duflo / Michael Kremer
  • 2020: Paul Milgrom / Robert B. Wilson
  • 2021: David Card / Joshua Angrist / Guido Imbens
  • 2022: Ben Bernanke / Douglas Diamond / Philip H. Dybvig
  • 2023: Claudia Goldin
  • 1991 Nobel Prize laureates

    Chemistry

    Richard R. Ernst (Switzerland)

    Literature (1991)

    Nadine Gordimer (South Africa)

    Peace

    Aung San Suu Kyi (Burma)

    Physics

    Pierre-Gilles de Gennes (France)

    Physiology or Medicine

  • Bert Sakmann (Germany)
  • Economic Sciences

    Ronald Coase (United Kingdom)

    Nobel Prize recipients
    1986
    1987
    1988
    1989
    1990
    1991
    1992
    1993
    1994
    1995
    1996

    By owner

  • Common
  • Communal
  • Community
  • Crown
  • Customary
  • Cooperative
  • Private
  • Public
  • Self
  • Social
  • State
  • Unowned
  • By nature

  • Croft
  • Intangible
  • Intellectual
  • Personal
  • Tangible
  • Commons

  • Common-pool resource
  • Digital
  • Global
  • Information
  • Knowledge
  • Theory

  • Commodity
  • Common good (economics)
  • Excludability
  • First possession
  • Free-rider problem
  • Game theory
  • Georgism
  • Gift economy
  • Labor theory of property
  • Law of rent
  • Legal plunder
  • Natural rights
  • Ownership
  • Property rights
  • Right to property
  • Rivalry
  • Tragedy of the commons
  • Applications

  • Ejido (agrarian land)
  • Forest types
  • Huerta
  • Inheritance
  • Land tenure
  • Property law
  • Rights

  • Fishing
  • Forest-dwelling (India)
  • Freedom to roam
  • Grazing
  • Hunting
  • Land
  • Littoral
  • Mineral
  • Right of way (transit)
  • Right of way (property access)
  • Water
  • Disposession/
    redistribution

  • Collectivization
  • Eminent domain
  • Enclosure
  • Eviction
  • Expropriation
  • Farhud
  • Forced migration
  • Illegal fishing
  • Illegal logging
  • Land Back
  • Land reform
  • Legal plunder
  • Piracy
  • Poaching
  • Primitive accumulation
  • Privatization
  • Regulatory taking
  • Slavery
  • Tax
  • Theft
  • Scholars
    (key work)

  • Ronald Coase
  • Friedrich Engels
  • Henry George
  • Garrett Hardin
  • David Harvey
  • John Locke
  • Karl Marx
  • Marcel Mauss
  • John Stuart Mill
  • Elinor Ostrom
  • Karl Polanyi
  • Pierre-Joseph Proudhon
  • David Ricardo
  • Murray N. Rothbard
  • Jean-Jacques Rousseau
  • Adam Smith
  • Property law
  • International

  • ISNI
  • VIAF
  • WorldCat
  • National

  • France
  • BnF data
  • Catalonia
  • Germany
  • Israel
  • Belgium
  • United States
  • Sweden
  • Latvia
  • Japan
  • Czech Republic
  • Australia
  • Korea
  • Netherlands
  • Poland
  • Academics

  • Google Scholar
  • Artists

    Other

  • IdRef

  • Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Ronald_Coase&oldid=1234780174"

    Categories: 
    1910 births
    2013 deaths
    Alumni of University of London Worldwide
    Alumni of the University of London
    Alumni of the London School of Economics
    English business theorists
    British economics writers
    Law and economics scholars
    Historians of economic thought
    Nobel laureates in Economics
    People educated at Kilburn Grammar School
    People from Willesden
    University at Buffalo faculty
    University of Chicago faculty
    University of Virginia faculty
    English centenarians
    British men centenarians
    University of Virginia alumni
    English Nobel laureates
    British Nobel laureates
    20th-century English historians
    20th-century English male writers
    21st-century English historians
    20th-century British economists
    21st-century British economists
    New institutional economists
    Environmental economists
    Cato Institute people
    Academics of the University of Dundee
    Earhart Foundation Fellows
    Distinguished Fellows of the American Economic Association
    Academics of the London School of Economics
    Corresponding Fellows of the British Academy
    Chicago School economists
    Member of the Mont Pelerin Society
    Burials at Graceland Cemetery (Chicago)
    Hidden categories: 
    CS1: long volume value
    CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list
    Articles with short description
    Short description is different from Wikidata
    Use British English from September 2013
    Use dmy dates from November 2022
    Articles with hCards
    Nobelprize template using Wikidata property P8024
    Articles with Internet Archive links
    Articles with FAST identifiers
    Articles with ISNI identifiers
    Articles with VIAF identifiers
    Articles with WorldCat Entities identifiers
    Articles with BIBSYS identifiers
    Articles with BNF identifiers
    Articles with BNFdata identifiers
    Articles with CANTICN identifiers
    Articles with GND identifiers
    Articles with J9U identifiers
    Articles with KBR identifiers
    Articles with LCCN identifiers
    Articles with Libris identifiers
    Articles with LNB identifiers
    Articles with NDL identifiers
    Articles with NKC identifiers
    Articles with NLA identifiers
    Articles with NLK identifiers
    Articles with NTA identifiers
    Articles with PLWABN identifiers
    Articles with CINII identifiers
    Articles with Google Scholar identifiers
    Articles with ULAN identifiers
    Articles with SNAC-ID identifiers
    Articles with SUDOC identifiers
     



    This page was last edited on 16 July 2024, at 03:13 (UTC).

    Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License 4.0; additional terms may apply. By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., a non-profit organization.



    Privacy policy

    About Wikipedia

    Disclaimers

    Contact Wikipedia

    Code of Conduct

    Developers

    Statistics

    Cookie statement

    Mobile view



    Wikimedia Foundation
    Powered by MediaWiki