Jump to content
 







Main menu
   


Navigation  



Main page
Contents
Current events
Random article
About Wikipedia
Contact us
Donate
 




Contribute  



Help
Learn to edit
Community portal
Recent changes
Upload file
 








Search  

































Create account

Log in
 









Create account
 Log in
 




Pages for logged out editors learn more  



Contributions
Talk
 



















Contents

   



(Top)
 


1 Voting process  





2 Variants and relationships to other methods  





3 Bucklin applied to multiwinner elections  





4 History and usage  





5 Satisfied and failed criteria  





6 Example application  





7 Voter strategy  





8 See also  





9 References  





10 Notes  














Bucklin voting






Deutsch
فارسی
Magyar

 

Edit links
 









Article
Talk
 

















Read
Edit
View history
 








Tools
   


Actions  



Read
Edit
View history
 




General  



What links here
Related changes
Upload file
Special pages
Permanent link
Page information
Cite this page
Get shortened URL
Download QR code
Wikidata item
 




Print/export  



Download as PDF
Printable version
 
















Appearance
   

 






From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
 


Bucklin voting is a class of voting methods that can be used for single-member and multi-member districts. As in highest median rules like the majority judgment, the Bucklin winner will be one of the candidates with the highest median ranking or rating. It is named after its original promoter, the Georgist politician[1] James W. BucklinofGrand Junction, Colorado, and is also known as the Grand Junction system.

Voting process[edit]

Bucklin rules varied, but here is a typical example:

Voters are allowed rank preference ballots (first, second, third, etc.).

First choice votes are first counted. If one candidate has a majority, that candidate wins. Otherwise the second choices are added to the first choices. Again, if a candidate with a majority vote is found, the winner is the candidate with the most votes accumulated. Lower rankings are added as needed.

Amajority is determined based on the number of valid ballots. Since, after the first round, there may be more votes cast than voters, it is possible for more than one candidate to have majority support.

Variants and relationships to other methods[edit]

The term Bucklin voting refers to the process of counting all votes on all ballots that are above some threshold, and then adjusting that threshold down until a majority is reached. In some variants which have been used, equal ranking was allowed at some or all ranks. Some variants had a predetermined number of ranks available (usually 2 or 3), while others had unlimited ranks. There were also variants akin to Borda voting in that lower-ranked votes counted for less.

The Bucklin procedure is one way to ensure that the winning candidate will be among those with the highest median vote. When used with a cardinal voting scale instead of ordinal ranking, Bucklin's balloting method is the same as that of highest median rules like the Majority Judgment. However, Bucklin's selection algorithm starts with the highest rated votes and adds lower ones until a median winner is reached, whereas Majority Judgment starts with the median votes and removes them until all but one candidate is eliminated. Due to this difference, Bucklin passes some voting criteria that Majority Judgment fails, and vice versa.

Bucklin applied to multiwinner elections[edit]

Bucklin was used for multiwinner elections. [citation needed] For multi-member districts, voters marked as many first choices as there are seats to be filled. Voters marked the same number of second and further choices. In some localities, the voter was required to mark a full set of first choices for his or her ballot to be valid. However, allowing voters to cast three simultaneous votes for three seats (block voting) could allow an organized 51%, or the largest minority in a contest with three or more slates, to win all three seats in the first round, so this method does not give proportional representation.

History and usage[edit]

The method was proposed by Condorcet in 1793.[2] It was re-invented under its current name and used in many political elections in the United States in the early 20th century, as were other experimental election methods during the progressive era. Bucklin voting was first used in 1909 in Grand Junction, Colorado, and then used in more than sixty other cities including Denver and San Francisco.[3][4]

In two states, it was found to violate the state constitution and overturned; in the remainder of states using it, it was repealed. In Minnesota, it was ruled unconstitutional, in a decision that disallowed votes for multiple candidates, in opposition to some voters' single expressed preference,[5] and in a variant used in Oklahoma, the particular application required voters in multi-candidate elections to rank more than one candidate, or the vote would not be counted; and the preferential primary was therefore found unconstitutional. The canvassing method itself was not rejected in Oklahoma.[6]

Adoption by Location[a]
State Election Year Adopted Notes
Washington State Primaries 1907 Predates traditional Bucklin voting and is slightly modified: candidates could win with 40% of the vote. The idea may have been based on a proposed primary law for Wisconsin suggested by Governor La Follete a year earlier.[7]
Colorado Grand Junction 1909
Washington Spokane 1910
Colorado Pueblo 1911
Louisiana New Iberia 1912
Minnesota Duluth 1913
Colorado Denver 1913
Colorado Colorado Springs 1913
Oregon Portland 1913
New Hampshire Nashua 1913
Ohio Cleveland 1913
Colorado Fort Collins 1913
Oregon La Grande 1913
California San Francisco 1917
Sources[8]

Satisfied and failed criteria[edit]

Bucklin voting satisfies the majority criterion, the mutual majority criterion and the monotonicity criterion.[9]

Bucklin voting without equal rankings allowed[clarification needed] fails the Condorcet criterion, independence of clones criterion,[10] later-no-harm, participation, consistency, reversal symmetry, the Condorcet loser criterion and the independence of irrelevant alternatives criterion.

If equal and skipped rankings are allowed, Bucklin passes or fails the same criteria as highest median rules like the Majority Judgment.

Example application[edit]

  • t
  • e
  • Tennessee and its four major cities: Memphis in the far west; Nashville in the center; Chattanooga in the east; and Knoxville in the far northeast

    Suppose that Tennessee is holding an election on the location of its capital. The population is concentrated around four major cities. All voters want the capital to be as close to them as possible. The options are:

    The preferences of each region's voters are:

    42% of voters
    Far-West
    26% of voters
    Center
    15% of voters
    Center-East
    17% of voters
    Far-East
    1. Memphis
    2. Nashville
    3. Chattanooga
    4. Knoxville
    1. Nashville
    2. Chattanooga
    3. Knoxville
    4. Memphis
    1. Chattanooga
    2. Knoxville
    3. Nashville
    4. Memphis
    1. Knoxville
    2. Chattanooga
    3. Nashville
    4. Memphis


    City Round 1 Round 2
    Memphis 42 42
    Nashville 26 68
    Chattanooga 15 58
    Knoxville 17 32

    The first round has no majority winner. Therefore, the second rank votes are added. This moves Nashville and Chattanooga above 50%, so a winner can be determined. Since Nashville is supported by a higher majority (68% versus 58%), Nashville is the winner.

    Voter strategy[edit]

    Voters supporting a strong candidate have an incentive to bullet vote (offer only one first-rank vote), in hopes that other voters will add enough votes to help their candidate win. This strategy is most secure if the supported candidate appears likely to gain many second-rank votes.

    In the above example, Memphis voters have the most first-place votes and might not offer a second preference in hopes of winning, but the strategy fails, unless other voters also bullet vote, because they are not a second-place choice of competitors.

    If all Memphis voters bullet vote, Chattanooga voters could cause their city to win by all bullet voting. However, if all Nashville voters also do the same, Memphis would win on the fourth and final round. In that case, Knoxville voters could do nothing to change the outcome.

    In this particular example (but not always), bullet voting benefits one group of voters only if another group or groups do it as well. The example shows that, depending upon who does it, bullet voting may distort the outcome and could be counterproductive for some voters who do it (here, those from Chattanooga and Nashville).

    To prevent bullet voting, voters could be required to rank all candidates on the ballot. This would provide the voter with a disincentive to bullet vote, as the vote would not be counted unless all candidates are ranked.

    See also[edit]

    References[edit]

    Specific
    1. ^ Hermann, J. R. "A Remembrance of James W. Bucklin". Single Tax Review, Vol. XIX, No.2, March-April 1919. http://cooperative-individualism.org/hermann-j-r_a-remembrance-of-james-bucklin-1919.htm
  • ^ Principles and problems of government, Haines and Hanes, 1921
  • ^ Barber, Kathleen L. (2000). A Right to Representation: Proportional Election Systems for the Twenty-first Century. Ohio State University Press. p. 167. ISBN 9780814208540.
  • ^ Kneier, Charles Mayard (1957). City government in the United States. Harper. pp. 365–370. OCLC 610214970.
  • ^ Brown v. Smallwood, 130 Minn. 492, 153 N. W. 953
  • ^ "Dove v. Oglesby". oscn.net.
  • ^ Merriam, Charles Edward (1908). Primary Elections: A Study of the History and Tendencies of Primary Election Legislation. University of Chicago Press.
  • ^ Mason, Haven A.; Locke, William James (1914). Pacific Municipalities.
  • ^ Collective decisions and voting: the potential for public choice, Nicolaus Tideman, 2006, p. 204
  • ^ Tideman, 2006, ibid
  • General

    Notes[edit]

    1. ^ All instances of this system were later abolished, but the dates are unknown.

    Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Bucklin_voting&oldid=1225085526"

    Categories: 
    Non-proportional multi-winner electoral systems
    Single-winner electoral systems
    Preferential electoral systems
    Non-monotonic electoral systems
    Hidden categories: 
    Articles with short description
    Short description matches Wikidata
    All articles with unsourced statements
    Articles with unsourced statements from November 2008
    Wikipedia articles needing clarification from February 2019
     



    This page was last edited on 22 May 2024, at 08:26 (UTC).

    Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License 4.0; additional terms may apply. By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., a non-profit organization.



    Privacy policy

    About Wikipedia

    Disclaimers

    Contact Wikipedia

    Code of Conduct

    Developers

    Statistics

    Cookie statement

    Mobile view



    Wikimedia Foundation
    Powered by MediaWiki