Jump to content
 







Main menu
   


Navigation  



Main page
Contents
Current events
Random article
About Wikipedia
Contact us
Donate
 




Contribute  



Help
Learn to edit
Community portal
Recent changes
Upload file
 








Search  

































Create account

Log in
 









Create account
 Log in
 




Pages for logged out editors learn more  



Contributions
Talk
 



















Contents

   



(Top)
 


1 Description of the method  



1.1  Football analogy  





1.2  Formal definition  



1.2.1  Variants of the pairwise score  









2 Satisfied and failed criteria  





3 Examples  



3.1  Example with Condorcet winner  





3.2  Example with Condorcet winner that is not elected winner (for pairwise opposition)  





3.3  Example without Condorcet winner  







4 See also  





5 References  





6 External links  














Minimax Condorcet method






فارسی
 

Edit links
 









Article
Talk
 

















Read
Edit
View history
 








Tools
   


Actions  



Read
Edit
View history
 




General  



What links here
Related changes
Upload file
Special pages
Permanent link
Page information
Cite this page
Get shortened URL
Download QR code
Wikidata item
 




Print/export  



Download as PDF
Printable version
 
















Appearance
   

 






From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
 


Invoting systems, the Minimax Condorcet method is a single-winner ranked-choice voting method that always elects the majority (Condorcet) winner.[1] Minimax compares all candidates against each other in a round-robin tournament, then ranks candidates by their worst election result (the result where they would receive the fewest votes). The candidate with the largest (maximum) number of votes in their worst (minimum) matchup is declared the winner.

Description of the method

[edit]

The Minimax Condorcet method selects the candidate for whom the greatest pairwise score for another candidate against him or her is the least such score among all candidates.

Football analogy

[edit]

Imagine politicians compete like football teams in a round-robin tournament, where every team plays against every other team once. In each matchup, a candidate's score is equal to the number of voters who support them over their opponent.

Minimax finds each team's (or candidate's) worst game – the one where they received the smallest number of points (votes). Each team's tournament score is equal to the number of points they got in their worst game. The first place in the tournament goes to the team with the best tournament score.

Formal definition

[edit]

Formally, let denote the pairwise score for against . Then the candidate, selected by minimax (aka the winner) is given by:

Variants of the pairwise score

[edit]

When it is permitted to rank candidates equally, or not rank all candidates, three interpretations of the rule are possible. When voters must rank all the candidates, all three variants are equivalent.

Let be the number of voters ranking X over Y. The variants define the score for candidate X against Y as:

  1. The number of voters ranking X above Y, but only when this score exceeds the number of voters ranking Y above X. If not, then the score for X against Y is zero. This variant is sometimes called winning votes is the most commonly used and preferred by social choice theorists.
  2. The number of voters ranking X above Y minus the number of voters ranking Y above X. This variant is called margins, and is less used.
  3. The number of voters ranking X above Y, regardless of whether more voters rank X above Y or vice versa. This variant is called pairwise opposition, and is also rarely used.

When one of the first two variants is used, the method can be restated as: "Disregard the weakest pairwise defeat until one candidate is unbeaten." An "unbeaten" candidate possesses a maximum score against him which is zero or negative.

Satisfied and failed criteria

[edit]

Minimax using winning votesormargins satisfies the Condorcet and the majority criterion, but not the Smith criterion, mutual majority criterion, or Condorcet loser criterion. When winning votes is used, minimax also satisfies the plurality criterion.

Minimax fails independence of irrelevant alternatives, independence of clones, local independence of irrelevant alternatives, and independence of Smith-dominated alternatives.[citation needed]

With the pairwise opposition variant (sometimes called MMPO), minimax only satisfies the majority-strength Condorcet criterion; a candidate with a relative majority over every other may not be elected. MMPO is a later-no-harm system and also satisfies sincere favorite criterion.

Nicolaus Tideman modified minimax to only drop edges that create Condorcet cycles, allowing his method to satisfy many of the above properties. Schulze's method similarly reduces to minimax when there are only three candidates.

Examples

[edit]

Example with Condorcet winner

[edit]

  • t
  • e
  • Tennessee and its four major cities: Memphis in the far west; Nashville in the center; Chattanooga in the east; and Knoxville in the far northeast

    Suppose that Tennessee is holding an election on the location of its capital. The population is concentrated around four major cities. All voters want the capital to be as close to them as possible. The options are:

    The preferences of each region's voters are:

    42% of voters
    Far-West
    26% of voters
    Center
    15% of voters
    Center-East
    17% of voters
    Far-East
    1. Memphis
    2. Nashville
    3. Chattanooga
    4. Knoxville
    1. Nashville
    2. Chattanooga
    3. Knoxville
    4. Memphis
    1. Chattanooga
    2. Knoxville
    3. Nashville
    4. Memphis
    1. Knoxville
    2. Chattanooga
    3. Nashville
    4. Memphis


    The results of the pairwise scores would be tabulated as follows:

    Pairwise election results
    X
    Memphis Nashville Chattanooga Knoxville
    Y Memphis [X] 58%
    [Y] 42%
    [X] 58%
    [Y] 42%
    [X] 58%
    [Y] 42%
    Nashville [X] 42%
    [Y] 58%
    [X] 32%
    [Y] 68%
    [X] 32%
    [Y] 68%
    Chattanooga [X] 42%
    [Y] 58%
    [X] 68%
    [Y] 32%
    [X] 17%
    [Y] 83%
    Knoxville [X] 42%
    [Y] 58%
    [X] 68%
    [Y] 32%
    [X] 83%
    [Y] 17%
    Pairwise election results (won-tied-lost): 0-0-3 3-0-0 2-0-1 1-0-2
    worst pairwise defeat (winning votes): 58% 0% 68% 83%
    worst pairwise defeat (margins): 16% −16% 36% 66%
    worst pairwise opposition: 58% 42% 68% 83%

    Result: In all three alternatives Nashville has the lowest value and is elected winner.

    Example with Condorcet winner that is not elected winner (for pairwise opposition)

    [edit]

    Assume three candidates A, B and C and voters with the following preferences:

    4% of voters 47% of voters 43% of voters 6% of voters
    1. A and C 1. A 1. C 1. B
    2. C 2. B 2. A and C
    3. B 3. B 3. A

    The results would be tabulated as follows:

    Pairwise election results
    X
    A B C
    Y A [X] 49%
    [Y] 51%
    [X] 43%
    [Y] 47%
    B [X] 51%
    [Y] 49%
    [X] 94%
    [Y] 6%
    C [X] 47%
    [Y] 43%
    [X] 6%
    [Y] 94%
    Pairwise election results (won-tied-lost): 2-0-0 0-0-2 1-0-1
    worst pairwise defeat (winning votes): 0% 94% 47%
    worst pairwise defeat (margins): −2% 88% 4%
    worst pairwise opposition: 49% 94% 47%

    Result: With the winning votes and margins alternatives, the Condorcet winner A is declared Minimax winner. However, using the pairwise opposition alternative, C is declared winner, since less voters strongly oppose him in his worst pairwise score against A than A is opposed by in his worst pairwise score against B.

    Example without Condorcet winner

    [edit]

    Assume four candidates A, B, C and D. Voters are allowed to not consider some candidates (denoting an n/a in the table), so that their ballots are not taken into account for pairwise scores of that candidates.

    30 voters 15 voters 14 voters 6 voters 4 voters 16 voters 14 voters 3 voters
    1. A 1. D 1. D 1. B 1. D 1. C 1. B 1. C
    2. C 2. B 2. B 2. C 2. C 2. A and B 2. C 2. A
    3. B 3. A 3. C 3. A 3. A and B
    4. D 4. C 4. A 4. D
    n/a D n/a A and D n/a B and D

    The results would be tabulated as follows:

    Pairwise election results
    X
    A B C D
    Y A [X] 35
    [Y] 30
    [X] 43
    [Y] 45
    [X] 33
    [Y] 36
    B [X] 30
    [Y] 35
    [X] 50
    [Y] 49
    [X] 33
    [Y] 36
    C [X] 45
    [Y] 43
    [X] 49
    [Y] 50
    [X] 33
    [Y] 36
    D [X] 36
    [Y] 33
    [X] 36
    [Y] 33
    [X] 36
    [Y] 33
    Pairwise election results (won-tied-lost): 2-0-1 2-0-1 2-0-1 0-0-3
    worst pairwise defeat (winning votes): 35 50 45 36
    worst pairwise defeat (margins): 5 1 2 3
    worst pairwise opposition: 43 50 49 36

    Result: Each of the three alternatives gives another winner:

    See also

    [edit]

    References

    [edit]
    1. ^ "[EM] the name of the rose". lists.electorama.com. Retrieved 2024-02-12.
    [edit]
    Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Minimax_Condorcet_method&oldid=1225085612"

    Category: 
    Monotonic Condorcet methods
    Hidden categories: 
    Articles with short description
    Short description is different from Wikidata
    All articles with unsourced statements
    Articles with unsourced statements from April 2024
     



    This page was last edited on 22 May 2024, at 08:26 (UTC).

    Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License 4.0; additional terms may apply. By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., a non-profit organization.



    Privacy policy

    About Wikipedia

    Disclaimers

    Contact Wikipedia

    Code of Conduct

    Developers

    Statistics

    Cookie statement

    Mobile view



    Wikimedia Foundation
    Powered by MediaWiki