Jump to content
 







Main menu
   


Navigation  



Main page
Contents
Current events
Random article
About Wikipedia
Contact us
Donate
 




Contribute  



Help
Learn to edit
Community portal
Recent changes
Upload file
 








Search  

































Create account

Log in
 









Create account
 Log in
 




Pages for logged out editors learn more  



Contributions
Talk
 



















Contents

   



(Top)
 


1 Derivation of equation  





2 Income plus capital gains equals total return  





3 Growth cannot exceed cost of equity  





4 Some properties of the model  





5 Problems with the constant-growth form of the model  





6 Related methods  





7 References  





8 Further reading  





9 External links  














Dividend discount model






Deutsch
Español
فارسی
Français

עברית
Polski
Português
Русский
Svenska

 

Edit links
 









Article
Talk
 

















Read
Edit
View history
 








Tools
   


Actions  



Read
Edit
View history
 




General  



What links here
Related changes
Upload file
Special pages
Permanent link
Page information
Cite this page
Get shortened URL
Download QR code
Wikidata item
 




Print/export  



Download as PDF
Printable version
 
















Appearance
   

 






From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
 



In financial economics, the dividend discount model (DDM) is a method of valuing the price of a company's capital stock or business value based on the fact that their corresponding value is worth the sum of all of its future dividend payments, discounted back to their present value.[1] In other words, DDM is used to value stocks based on the net present value of the future dividends. The constant-growth form of the DDM is sometimes referred to as the Gordon growth model (GGM), after Myron J. Gordon of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, the University of Rochester, and the University of Toronto, who published it along with Eli Shapiro in 1956 and made reference to it in 1959.[2][3] Their work borrowed heavily from the theoretical and mathematical ideas found in John Burr Williams 1938 book "The Theory of Investment Value," which put forth the dividend discount model 18 years before Gordon and Shapiro.

When dividends are assumed to grow at a constant rate, the variables are: is the current stock price. is the constant growth rate in perpetuity expected for the dividends. is the constant cost of equity capital for that company. is the value of dividends at the end of the first period.

Derivation of equation[edit]

The model uses the fact that the current value of the dividend payment at (discrete) time is, and so the current value of all the future dividend payments, which is the current price , is the sum of the infinite series

This summation can be rewritten as

where

The series in parentheses is the geometric series with common ratio so it sums to if. Thus,

Substituting the value for leads to

,

which is simplified by multiplying by , so that

Income plus capital gains equals total return[edit]

The DDM equation can also be understood to state simply that a stock's total return equals the sum of its income and capital gains.

is rearranged to give

So the dividend yield plus the growth equals cost of equity .

Consider the dividend growth rate in the DDM model as a proxy for the growth of earnings and by extension the stock price and capital gains. Consider the DDM's cost of equity capital as a proxy for the investor's required total return.[4]

Growth cannot exceed cost of equity[edit]

From the first equation, one might notice that cannot be negative. When growth is expected to exceed the cost of equity in the short run, then usually a two-stage DDM is used:

Therefore,

where denotes the short-run expected growth rate, denotes the long-run growth rate, and is the period (number of years), over which the short-run growth rate is applied.

Even when g is very close to r, P approaches infinity, so the model becomes meaningless.

Some properties of the model[edit]

a) When the growth g is zero, the dividend is capitalized.

.

b) This equation is also used to estimate the cost of capital by solving for .

c) which is equivalent to the formula of the Gordon Growth Model (or Yield-plus-growth Model):

=

where “” stands for the present stock value, “” stands for expected dividend per share one year from the present time, “g” stands for rate of growth of dividends, and “k” represents the required return rate for the equity investor.

Problems with the constant-growth form of the model[edit]

The following shortcomings have been noted;[citation needed] See also Discounted cash flow § Shortcomings.

  1. The presumption of a steady and perpetual growth rate less than the cost of capital may not be reasonable.
  2. If the stock does not currently pay a dividend, like many growth stocks, more general versions of the discounted dividend model must be used to value the stock. One common technique is to assume that the Modigliani–Miller hypothesis of dividend irrelevance is true, and therefore replace the stock's dividend D with E earnings per share. However, this requires the use of earnings growth rather than dividend growth, which might be different. This approach is especially useful for computing the residual value of future periods.
  3. The stock price resulting from the Gordon model is sensitive to the growth rate chosen; see Sustainable growth rate § From a financial perspective

Related methods[edit]

The dividend discount model is closely related to both discounted earnings and discounted cashflow models. In either of the latter two, the value of a company is based on how much money is made by the company. For example, if a company consistently paid out 50% of earnings as dividends, then the discounted dividends would be worth 50% of the discounted earnings. Also, in the dividend discount model, a company that is not expected to pay dividends ever in the future is worth nothing, as the owners of the asset ultimately never receive any cash.

References[edit]

  • ^ Gordon, M.J and Eli Shapiro (1956) "Capital Equipment Analysis: The Required Rate of Profit," Management Science, 3,(1) (October 1956) 102-110. Reprinted in Management of Corporate Capital, Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press of, 1959.
  • ^ Gordon, Myron J. (1959). "Dividends, Earnings and Stock Prices". Review of Economics and Statistics. 41 (2). The MIT Press: 99–105. doi:10.2307/1927792. JSTOR 1927792.
  • ^ "Spreadsheet for variable inputs to Gordon Model". Archived from the original on 2019-03-22. Retrieved 2011-12-28.
  • Further reading[edit]

    External links[edit]


    Retrieved from "https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Dividend_discount_model&oldid=1234458449"

    Categories: 
    Stock market
    Financial models
    Economics models
    Valuation (finance)
    Hidden categories: 
    Articles needing additional references from May 2023
    All articles needing additional references
    Articles with short description
    Short description is different from Wikidata
    All articles with unsourced statements
    Articles with unsourced statements from November 2020
    CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list
     



    This page was last edited on 14 July 2024, at 13:29 (UTC).

    Text is available under the Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License 4.0; additional terms may apply. By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. Wikipedia® is a registered trademark of the Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., a non-profit organization.



    Privacy policy

    About Wikipedia

    Disclaimers

    Contact Wikipedia

    Code of Conduct

    Developers

    Statistics

    Cookie statement

    Mobile view



    Wikimedia Foundation
    Powered by MediaWiki